01.05.2014 Views

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

Research 350 - NZ Transport Agency

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT BENEFITS OF TRANSPORT INVESTMENT<br />

use of I-O analysis in combination with SCBA may allow policymakers to choose between<br />

conflicting goals (without indicating whether one methodology should be preferred as a<br />

decision-making tool). Preference for I-O results over SCBA would seem questionable in the<br />

long term, since it is not clear why the focus should not simply be on the development of<br />

efficient projects and thereby on efficient growth.<br />

A more useful approach would therefore be to base decision-making on the results of SCBA<br />

and then employ I-O if impacts analysis is required, taking account of the fact that I-O<br />

analysis is likely to provide upper bound macroeconomic results.<br />

Note that these outputs are quite different to those estimated by SCBA (i.e. project NPV and<br />

BCR). The comparison between I-O analysis and SCBA issue is further discussed below.<br />

2.6.2 General Equilibrium Analysis<br />

CGE modelling has often been suggested as an alternative to more traditional, project<br />

focussed, SCBA for two major reasons:<br />

• CGE models typically present the impacts of a given investment in transport (or other<br />

defined change in inputs) in terms of its effects on GDP, employment, investment,<br />

trade, consumption, wages and tax. As such, they are of particular interest to<br />

policymakers, who cannot obtain such economic impact data from SCBA. They are<br />

therefore said to allow for a ‘wider test’ of the public benefit then is obtainable<br />

through SCBA alone (Docwra & West 1999, pp. 933-934).<br />

• The use of a general rather than a partial equilibrium approach gives CGE modelling<br />

potential to capture the ‘missing benefits’, related to suggested ‘flow-on’ effects 12<br />

(Kinhill Economics 1999, pp. 10-11). This is particularly true for large projects which<br />

have major impacts on other sectors of the economy. Docwra & West argue that, in<br />

principle, a CGE model would be needed to measure the efficiency effects on such<br />

sectors (Docwra & West 1999, pp. 933-934).<br />

ACG has been particularly supportive of the use of CGE modelling in assessing the impacts of<br />

New Zealand and Australian transport investments (ACG 1993, 1996, 2003, 2004).<br />

As is the case with SCBA and I-O analysis, CGE has its drawbacks, including the following:<br />

• CGE models tend to be something of a ‘black box’ with key linkages and assumptions<br />

left undocumented. ACG (2004) provides some indications of the assumptions<br />

underlying the ESSAM model, though by their very nature, the operation of such<br />

models is arcane. Potential therefore exists for the incorporation of naïve or seriously<br />

misleading assumptions into model structures.<br />

• An often-cited advantage of CGE models, that they provide an insight into employment<br />

effects arising from transport investment, may be illusory. The BTE provides an<br />

extensive critique of past (Australian and international) attempts to analyse national<br />

employment outcomes from infrastructure projects using CGE modelling. Invariably<br />

the models are handicapped by a lack of knowledge regarding the labour supply and<br />

demand markets and the nature of wage adjustments. The BTE concludes that it is<br />

12 As noted above the distinction between the terms ‘partial’ and ‘general’ equilibrium can be somewhat<br />

blurred.<br />

48

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!