19.10.2014 Views

Promoting Financial Inclusion - United Nations Development ...

Promoting Financial Inclusion - United Nations Development ...

Promoting Financial Inclusion - United Nations Development ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

that benefits. The fact is that banks do not<br />

view such activities as profitable and, as a<br />

result, the roll out of the schemes is limited<br />

in scope and insipid in direction. For reasons<br />

of political economy this may not be the<br />

official line of bank managements but<br />

ultimately it is local managers and staff who<br />

determine the momentum of a rollout. If<br />

bankers saw significant potential business in<br />

these activities a more dynamic rollout with<br />

real momentum would be apparent. Thus,<br />

even the untested and unproven business<br />

correspondent model remains still born<br />

for lack of a business model, being limited<br />

largely to technology service providers<br />

opening “no frills” accounts that are largely<br />

dormant.<br />

So what is the solution? As an institution<br />

whose promoters have been engaged with<br />

issues of microfinance and financial inclusion<br />

for more than three decades, M-CRIL has<br />

a deep understanding of the issues. The two<br />

key problems emerging from this report<br />

and M-CRIL’s overall experience are set<br />

out in the following sub-sections.<br />

4.2 THE IMPACT OF INTEREST RATE<br />

DE-REGULATION – WHAT ABOUT THE<br />

POLITICAL CONSTRAINTS?<br />

It has been repeatedly observed in this report<br />

that low transaction volumes in small value<br />

accounts entail very high proportionate<br />

costs for the banks. For many years bankers<br />

were forced by regulation to cross-subsidise<br />

financial inclusion activities. They were<br />

required to offer small value services to low<br />

income families at the lowest interest rates<br />

in the system. The well known differential<br />

rate of interest scheme (requiring banks to<br />

lend at 4% interest, well below their cost of<br />

funds) still exists, though it now accounts<br />

for a minuscule proportion of their total<br />

portfolio. Even after general interest rate<br />

deregulation in the late 1990s, interest<br />

ceilings (defined as the prime lending rate,<br />

the minimum, “risk free rate” to be charged<br />

by the bank) continued for small value<br />

accounts. As a result of decades of social<br />

control of interest rates, it has become<br />

ingrained in the public mind that “loans for<br />

the poor” should be subsidized. The reality<br />

of credit rationing resulting from such<br />

subsidies is lost on the average observer.<br />

Within the past months, all interest<br />

rate regulation has been abandoned. This<br />

must be welcomed in that it constitutes<br />

official recognition that bankers must be<br />

allowed to determine the parameters of<br />

their own business. However, the rhetoric<br />

of “reasonableness” pervades all circulars<br />

from the Reserve Bank of India and<br />

pronouncements by the government. While<br />

there is no case for profiteering from those<br />

living on low incomes, the message of this<br />

rhetoric is inevitably that some element of<br />

cross-subsidisation must continue. But the<br />

result of any such action is a higher than<br />

optimal price for those provided services<br />

on a viable basis and a lower than optimal<br />

volume for those receiving subsidised<br />

services.<br />

It is notable that the rural banking<br />

system (consisting of the District Central<br />

Cooperative BanksDCCBs and Regional<br />

Rural Banks - RRBs) has not had to<br />

follow interest rate regulation for over a<br />

decade now. Yet, at no point has it felt free<br />

to charge much more than the commercial<br />

banks for the apparently more inclusive<br />

services it provides. A study by M-CRIL in<br />

2008-09 showed that the average yields of<br />

DCCBs and RRBs were not significantly<br />

more than the 10.5% average yields of<br />

commercial banks (in 2007-08) despite<br />

the RRBs having operating expense ratios<br />

(OER) that were significantly higher (see<br />

Figure). While DCCB operating expense<br />

ratios were lower this was largely on account<br />

of most origination expenses being borne<br />

by the loss making Primary Agricultural<br />

Cooperative Credit Societies (PACS). It<br />

is apparent that the lower yields of the<br />

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY<br />

xv

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!