10.07.2015 Views

Untitled - socium.ge

Untitled - socium.ge

Untitled - socium.ge

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

158 Marshall Van Alstyne and Nathaniel Bulkleyencoded rules tacitly making them harder to express, (3) people who withholdprocess knowled<strong>ge</strong> benefit themselves at the expense of the firm, (4) differencesare really between seeking tips and volunteering facts as between questionerand answerer, and (5) style differences between mana<strong>ge</strong>rs who tellsubordinates what they want versus how to proceed.Procedural information often involves a tacit component. Difficulties ofsharing tacit information are widely recognized. Research on the learning ofskills sug<strong>ge</strong>sts that the transfer is greater the greater the overlap betweencomponents already acquired and those required for the performance of a newtask (Singley and Anderson, 1989). Studies of technology transfer furthersug<strong>ge</strong>st that when people are motivated to share information the difficulty istypically related to the complexity of the information (Hansen, 1999). Tworelevant dimensions of complexity are the level of codification (Winter, 1987;Zander and Kogut, 1995) and the extent to which information to be transferredis an element of a set of interdependent components (Treece, 1986; Winter,1987).Efficiency gains accrue to the sharing of complementary information. Iftwo people share no common understanding, each will be unable to connectinformation the other knows to anything he or she knows how to perform.Likewise, a person who knows everything another person knows gains nothingby exchanging information. Stated formally:Hypothesis 6b: Optimal sharing occurs between partners with partialinformation overlap.Within firms, interviews indicate that this would lar<strong>ge</strong>ly be true for peer-topeerrelations but self-reports of social network overlap show little correlationwith performance. Rather, status distinctions govern sharing: “Facts are sharedin all directions. Methods flow downward. A partner would never ask an associate[consultant] ‘How would you do this?’” (interview data).In moving from individual to organizational levels of analysis, connectingpeople holding different kinds of knowled<strong>ge</strong> becomes important. Huberobserves that organizations often do not know what they know. In economicterms, such missed opportunities often lead to failed economies of scale orscope.Economies of scale arise because informational fixed costs (for example,learning, the investment in creating a first copy) are often high relative to themarginal costs involved in repeating a procedure (Arrow, 1974; Shapiro andVarian, 1999). Economies of scope arise when the joint cost of producing twodifferent outputs is less than the cost of producing them separately.Informational economies of scope arise from indivisibilities in the applicationof a specialized knowled<strong>ge</strong> base (Teece, 1980). Improvements may also takethe form of either informing the uninformed or drawing new insights frombridging disciplines.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!