21.12.2012 Views

Legal empowerment for local resource control

Legal empowerment for local resource control

Legal empowerment for local resource control

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Yet, overall, the security of <strong>resource</strong> rights is problematic <strong>for</strong> both <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

investors and <strong>local</strong> <strong>resource</strong> users in much of sub-Saharan Africa. This is due<br />

to ill-drafted and/or ill-coordinated laws, weak government capacity to<br />

en<strong>for</strong>ce them, limited effectiveness and independence of the judiciary and<br />

other factors.<br />

Within this, ef<strong>for</strong>ts to secure <strong>resource</strong> rights have tended to focus on <strong>for</strong>eign<br />

investment. As a result, the legal protection of <strong>resource</strong> rights tends to be<br />

differentiated: the <strong>resource</strong> rights of some are granted greater protection<br />

than those of others. This differentiation broadly reflects asymmetries in<br />

power relations between actors – with <strong>for</strong>eign investors tending to enjoy<br />

greater protection than <strong>local</strong> <strong>resource</strong> users.<br />

Universal principles but differentiated rules: the protection of property<br />

under international law as it applies to Africa<br />

At the international level, security of <strong>resource</strong> rights is influenced by the<br />

international rules on the protection of property. The right to property<br />

affirmed by international human rights law protects both the <strong>resource</strong> rights<br />

of <strong>local</strong> groups affected by large-scale investment projects, and the property<br />

rights of <strong>for</strong>eign investors. In addition, <strong>for</strong>eign investment is also protected<br />

under international economic law. This includes norms on the protection of<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign property, which extends to <strong>resource</strong> rights based on contracts<br />

between the investor and host state (e.g. <strong>for</strong>est or mining concessions). 10<br />

International economic law protecting <strong>for</strong>eign property emerged in the 19th<br />

century. In the 1960s and 70s, it <strong>for</strong>med the object of considerable debate<br />

between capital-exporting and capital-importing states. More recently,<br />

polarisations have given way to a significant strengthening of the protection of<br />

<strong>for</strong>eign property, in many respects well beyond the protection granted to<br />

nationals. This includes:<br />

The development of international rules on the taking of <strong>for</strong>eign property,<br />

particularly those establishing the conditions <strong>for</strong> the legality of takings<br />

(public purpose, non-discrimination, due process and payment of<br />

10. International arbitrators have consistently adopted a very broad definition of property rights, including<br />

“all interests and rights which […] may be evaluated in financial and economic terms” (Liamco v. Libya);<br />

and “any right which can be the object of a commercial transaction […] and has thus monetary value”<br />

(Amoco v. Iran). Broad definitions of property rights are also used in virtually all bilateral investment<br />

treaties. As a result, breaches of investors’ contractual rights have been treated as takings of property, with<br />

implications <strong>for</strong> the strength of the protection of <strong>for</strong>eign investors’ assets (see e.g. the cases BP v. Libya;<br />

Texaco v. Libya; Aminoil v. Kuwait).<br />

29

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!