21.12.2012 Views

Legal empowerment for local resource control

Legal empowerment for local resource control

Legal empowerment for local resource control

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

66<br />

central state to <strong>local</strong> governments – although evidence suggests that little<br />

practical use has been made of it. Also crucial is the extent to which <strong>local</strong><br />

governments depend on the central state <strong>for</strong> access to financial <strong>resource</strong>s.<br />

Re<strong>for</strong>m to strengthen the nature and broaden the content of the <strong>resource</strong><br />

rights vested with <strong>local</strong> <strong>resource</strong> users can increase <strong>local</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>control</strong>.<br />

Where recognition of ownership is not an option, this can be done through<br />

reducing the number and scope of conditions attached to the legal protection<br />

of use rights, such as productive use requirements; through the application of<br />

safeguards <strong>for</strong> expropriation (compensation, non-discrimination, public<br />

purpose and due process) to the taking of use rights; and through reducing<br />

central state <strong>control</strong> over <strong>local</strong> government decision-making.<br />

Land rights and rights over valuable <strong>resource</strong>s<br />

Even where stronger and/or broader land rights are vested with <strong>local</strong><br />

groups, their practical implications may depend on the extent to which they<br />

entail greater <strong>control</strong> over valuable <strong>resource</strong>s (timber, minerals) located<br />

above or below the land. As discussed above (chapter 2.2.2), this is rarely<br />

the case. However, in some countries, greater protection of land rights has<br />

been accompanied by devolution of (some degree of) <strong>control</strong> over other<br />

<strong>resource</strong>s.<br />

In Mozambique, <strong>for</strong> instance, a substantial portion of Mozambique’s land<br />

area is covered by <strong>for</strong>ests (78% according to Sitoe et al, 2003), and timber<br />

often constitutes the most valuable <strong>resource</strong> on the land. As a result, the<br />

livelihood implications of vesting land rights with “<strong>local</strong> communities” are<br />

affected by the interface between land legislation and <strong>for</strong>estry legislation<br />

(Forest and Wildlife Act 1999 and its Regulations). Forest legislation does<br />

accord some degree of protection to <strong>local</strong> tree rights. But it is more cautious<br />

than the Land Act in the scope of the rights it vests with “<strong>local</strong> communities”.<br />

In part, the Forest and Wildlife Act rein<strong>for</strong>ces the provisions of the Land Act,<br />

as it follows the same definition of “<strong>local</strong> community” (article 1(5)) and as it<br />

requires landholding communities to be consulted be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>for</strong>est concessions<br />

are issued (article 17(2)). In other words, <strong>local</strong> users and outsiders are<br />

expected to negotiate terms and conditions under which <strong>local</strong> users may<br />

benefit from the outside investment. In addition, <strong>local</strong> communities are to<br />

benefit from 20% of the <strong>for</strong>est tax revenue flowing from timber exploitation<br />

in their land. This rein<strong>for</strong>ces the <strong>resource</strong> use rights of <strong>local</strong> communities,

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!