06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 4. Negligence St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

3. Mass torts? If the bellwether strategy violates the parties’ due process rights, what is to<br />

be done in mass torts cases? As U.S. District Judge Jack Weinstein observed in Schwab v. Philip<br />

Morris U.S.A., Inc., 449 F. Supp. 2d 992 (E.D.N.Y. 2006):<br />

In mass fraud cases with hundreds of thous<strong>and</strong>s or millions of injured the cost of<br />

one-on-one procedures is insuperable <strong>and</strong> unsuitable for either a jury or a bench trial.<br />

The consequence of requiring individual proof from each smoker would be to allow<br />

a def0endant which has injured millions of people <strong>and</strong> caused billions of dollars in<br />

damages to escape almost all liability.<br />

Does excluding bellwether trials mean that the resolution of these cases will inevitably happen in<br />

settlements outside of the courtroom—settlements in which the party not holding the cash will be<br />

at a decided disadvantage?<br />

G. Negligence Puzzles<br />

We end our initial treatment of the negligence st<strong>and</strong>ard with three puzzles in the law of<br />

negligence:<br />

1. Should Wealth Matter?<br />

Should the defendant’s wealth matter in setting the reasonable care st<strong>and</strong>ard in a<br />

negligence case? Won’t wealthy actors often be able to go ahead with risky behavior, confident<br />

that the damages suffered by others will have little effect on their own relative wealth? Professors<br />

Ken Abraham <strong>and</strong> John Jeffrey argue the contrary. Wealth, they insist, should not matter if we<br />

want to achieve optimal deterrence:<br />

[T]he defendant’s wealth is irrelevant to deterrence. . . . Deterrence theory is based<br />

on the (usually <strong>and</strong> to one or another extent plausible) assumption that actors weigh<br />

the expected costs <strong>and</strong> benefits of their future actions. Specifically, a potentially<br />

liable defendant will compare the benefits it will derive from an action that risks<br />

tort liability against the discounted present expected value of the liability that will<br />

be imposed if the risk occurs. Whether a defendant is wealthy or poor, this costbenefit<br />

calculation is the same. If, as is likely, a wealthy defendant derives no<br />

greater benefit from a given action than a poor defendant, then both will be equally<br />

deterred (or equally undeterred) by the threat of tort liability. A defendant’s existing<br />

assets do not increase the expected value of a given future action. Therefore they<br />

do not require any adjustment in the level of sanction needed to offset that expected<br />

value. The defendant’s wealth or lack of it is thus irrelevant to the deterrence of<br />

socially undesirable conduct, <strong>and</strong> evidence on the subject is inadmissible in the<br />

typical tort action claiming compensatory damages.<br />

Kenneth Abraham & John Jeffries, Jr., Punitive Damages <strong>and</strong> the Rule of Law: The Role of<br />

Defendant’s Wealth, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 415, 417 (1989).<br />

250

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!