06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 10. Damages<br />

plaintiffs’ bar to make in lawsuits. Lester Brickman, an especially outspoken critic of contingency fees,<br />

argues that contingency fees have produced in the United States a massive, foolish, <strong>and</strong> unaccountable<br />

system of ad hoc regulation that lines the pockets of one group (the plaintiffs’ lawyers) while<br />

impoverishing virtually everyone else.<br />

American tort lawyers’ profits have risen prodigiously to levels far beyond what is<br />

necessary to create sufficient incentives for lawyers to provide access to the civil<br />

justice system. Lawyers justify their fees by saying that they bear the risks of losing<br />

the cases. And indeed, by chasing down business through advertising <strong>and</strong><br />

aggressive outreach, some lawyers appear to be among American society’s<br />

quintessential entrepreneurs. They invest <strong>and</strong> put at risk time <strong>and</strong> capital,<br />

sometimes amounting to millions of dollars in exchange for a percentage of an<br />

uncertain recovery. Professional athletes, rock stars, hedge fund managers, <strong>and</strong><br />

CEOs enjoy huge earnings. Why not lawyers? How can we say that their returns<br />

are excessive, so long as the field of play is level <strong>and</strong> they play an honest game?<br />

In actual fact, the field of play is tilted, the deck is stacked, the game is fixed. Many<br />

lawyers charge for entrepreneurial risks they don’t actually bear. By careful case<br />

selection, they prevail in the substantial majority of the cases they accept. Despite<br />

the limited risk, their share of damage awards routinely amounts to one third or<br />

more. Lawyers can charge for these phantom risks because they use positional<br />

advantages to shield themselves from market forces. They charge st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

contingency fees which are intended to compensate lawyers for the risks they are<br />

assuming, but do so even in cases where there is no meaningful liability risk <strong>and</strong> a<br />

high probability of a substantial recovery. They benefit from enormous economies<br />

of scale in class actions <strong>and</strong> other large scale litigations but do not share these<br />

benefits with their clients. . . .<br />

The quest for contingency super profits has led lawyers, in collaborative efforts with<br />

courts, to use the courts to secure outcomes which are indistinguishable from<br />

legislative acts <strong>and</strong> administrative rule-making. This “regulation through litigation”<br />

dilutes the democratic form of American government by exempting large areas of<br />

policy from legislative control. In effect, lawyers are using their positional<br />

advantages to convert policy making into a highly profitable enterprise. When<br />

public policy making is thus removed from legislatures, so too is political<br />

accountability <strong>and</strong> public participation in the process.<br />

Lester Brickman, Unmasking the Powerful Force that has Mis-Shaped the American Civil Justice<br />

System, 4 GLOBAL COMPETITION LITIG. REV. 169 (2010). Brickman exaggerates the problem; not<br />

all lawyers, of course, will be able to screen for low-risk cases, <strong>and</strong> lawyers near the bottom of the<br />

pecking order may take on cases with considerable risk. But Brickman makes an interesting<br />

observation: the very best lawyers are often able to select their cases carefully. They can screen<br />

for only the highest value claims, which are often the claims most certain to produce damages<br />

awards. And if that is so, then the market in legal services may systematically assign to the best<br />

lawyers not the hardest cases that warrant the greatest skills, but rather the easiest cases (in the<br />

sense of being most certain <strong>and</strong> thus often of highest value).<br />

Brickman’s proposed solution is what he calls the “early offer” proposal:<br />

643

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!