06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 8. Duty Problem<br />

contractual relationship with the defendant. See Doyle v. South Pittsburgh Water Co., 199 A.2d<br />

875, 878 (Pa. 1964). After the New York Court of Appeals decided Strauss, the New Jersey<br />

Supreme Court refused to immunize a defendant-utility company from liability arising outside of<br />

a contractual relationship. See Weinberg v. Dinger, 524 A.2d 366, 378 (N.J. 1987).<br />

The Restatement (Third) of <strong>Torts</strong> criticizes Moch. In particular, the Restatement notes:<br />

[t]he difficulty with [Moch] is that the provision of utilities creates an expectation<br />

of <strong>and</strong> reliance on continued service. When the utility ceases to supply service, the<br />

omission is much like ceasing to provide warning signals at a railroad crossing. . . .<br />

[R]eliance on the utility’s continuing to provide its services is a cause of harm.<br />

RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF TORTS: PHYS. & EMOT. HARM § 42 cmt. i (2012). Nevertheless, the<br />

New York Court of Appeals continues to apply Strauss <strong>and</strong> Moch, even in cases that do not<br />

involve utility companies. See, e.g., Espinal v. Melville Snow Contrs., 773 N.E.2d 485, 489 (N.Y.<br />

2002) (holding that defendant snow removal company owed the injured party no duty of care<br />

because the defendant contracted with the injured party’s employer, not the injured party himself).<br />

2. Scholarly reaction to Strauss. Certain scholars have criticized the Strauss court’s<br />

reasoning. For example, Professors Goldberg <strong>and</strong> Zipursky have stated that the plaintiff’s case for<br />

a duty was particularly strong in Strauss because “the very point in providing electricity to<br />

building owners is to provide for the needs <strong>and</strong> safety of their tenants.” John C.P. Goldberg &<br />

Benjamin C. Zipursky, The Restatement (Third) <strong>and</strong> the Place of Duty in Negligence Law, 54<br />

VAND. L. REV. 657, 719 (2001). The Strauss court, however, was concerned about the monetary<br />

burden “imposed on New York’s major electrical supplier” if the defendant-utility company was<br />

negligent. Id. Thus, the court disguised a policy rationale by issuing a “no duty decision.” Id.<br />

Other scholars have stated that New York courts “act like a legislature when deciding duty in<br />

[cases like Strauss].” Anthony J. Sebok, What’s Law Got to Do with It? Designing Compensation<br />

Schemes in the Shadow of the Tort System, 53 DEPAUL L. REV. 501, 516 (2001). Does a court<br />

have a non-legislative option in such cases?<br />

Professor Daniel Farber has praised the Strauss court: “Strauss created a triage rule,<br />

identifying a subclass of victims (those in privity of contract with the utility) whose claims<br />

seemed particularly deserving to the court. . . . [This rule] at least establish[es] the possibility of<br />

cutting potentially unmanageable cases down to size.” Daniel A. Farber, Tort Law in the Era of<br />

Climate Change, Katrina, <strong>and</strong> 9/11: Exploring Liability for Extraordinary Risks, 43 VAL. U. L.<br />

REV. 1075, 1128 (2009).<br />

3. Policy arguments? What other policy arguments would support the Strauss <strong>and</strong> Moch<br />

courts’ holdings? One court has considered consumer welfare as a reason to immunize utility<br />

companies from liability. According to the court’s analysis, liability would increase utility<br />

companies’ costs, which would be passed on to consumers in the form of higher utility rates. In<br />

contrast to insurance premiums, which vary according to the risk of loss, higher rates would be<br />

uniform for all consumers. The class of insurance company customers would form an ersatz<br />

insurance pool—but one in which the low-risk consumers would subsidize high-risk consumers.<br />

See Reimann v. Monmouth Consol. Water Co., 87 A.2d 325, 327 (N.J. 1952), overruled by<br />

Weinberg v. Dinger, 524 A.2d 366, 378 (N.J. 1987). Why won’t the costs be borne, as the<br />

421

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!