06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 10. Damages<br />

3. The incidence of workers’ compensation costs. Before the rise of m<strong>and</strong>atory workers’<br />

compensation, evidence indicates that workers in jobs with a high likelihood of workplace injuries<br />

received a “risk premium” of higher wages. Those premiums levelled out with the introduction of<br />

m<strong>and</strong>atory workers’ compensation. Workers’ compensation essentially forces employers to pay<br />

their workers in not just wages, but also insurance. Do workers get paid less in wages because<br />

some of their compensation is in the form of insurance? Historical data indicates that workers<br />

bore the brunt of the incidence of workers’ compensation costs through lower wages. Price V.<br />

Fishback & Shawn Kantor, Did Workers Gain from the Passage of Workers’ Compensation<br />

Laws? 110 Q.J. ECON. 713 (1995).<br />

Workers’ compensation laws do not preempt lawsuits against third parties, such as the<br />

tug-boat company that ferried O’Shea to work or the manufacturers of industrial equipment. If<br />

both the employer <strong>and</strong> the third party are at fault, they would have been held jointly <strong>and</strong> severally<br />

liable <strong>and</strong> thus shared the costs before the enactment of workers’ compensation. Under the<br />

current regime, the third party often bears the entire cost because the claim against the employer is<br />

pre-empted. Is this a positive development? On the one h<strong>and</strong>, these third parties may be held<br />

liable out of proportion to their damages; on the other h<strong>and</strong>, not immunizing the employers<br />

substantially undoes the quid pro quo of the workers’ compensation deal in which the employer<br />

provides certain compensation regardless of fault in return for immunity from suit in tort.<br />

4. The collateral source rule. If O’Shea had disability insurance, would that affect her tort<br />

award? Most likely not. The “collateral source rule” provides that the damages award a plaintiff<br />

receives shall not be affected by payments from third parties, such as insurers, to cover the cost of<br />

those injuries. RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 920A(2). This rule means that, in theory, a<br />

plaintiff could receive compensation from her property insurance company for damages to her<br />

house <strong>and</strong> receive compensation from the tortfeasor for those same damages. Note that while the<br />

collateral source rule makes sense from a deterrence perspective, it is hard to underst<strong>and</strong> if<br />

compensation is our goal. In a deterrence framework, the fact of the plaintiff’s insurance is<br />

irrelevant to the level at which the defendant should have to pay out in order to create optimal<br />

deterrence. In a compensation framework, a plaintiff who has already been made whole by an<br />

insurer will not need further compensation; at the very least, the high expenses of compensation<br />

through tort are likely unjustified purely for compensation purposes.<br />

Note that it is not always clear that the collateral source rule should be thought of as<br />

providing for double payment. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, the plaintiff may be recovering twice for the<br />

same damage, an apparent windfall. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the plaintiff has been paying insurance<br />

premiums for one payout, so the insurance payout is hardly a free windfall. Even if the collateral<br />

source rule allows double payment, is it necessary to preserve the deterrence effects of torts? Or,<br />

is it necessary to preserve an incentive to purchase insurance? Many states have passed<br />

legislation restricting the collateral source rule in some form to restrict the potential double<br />

payment to plaintiffs, most often in the context of medical insurance <strong>and</strong> malpractice claims.<br />

David Schap & Andrew Feeley, The Collateral Source Rule: Statutory Reform <strong>and</strong> Special<br />

Interests, 28 CATO J. 83, 89 (2008). Why should defendants get the benefit of a plaintiff’s<br />

insurance arrangements? The case for the traditional collateral source rule is especially clear in<br />

the context of private insurance, where the plaintiff has paid (often very high) premiums to be<br />

protected. But even with respect to public insurance mechanisms, why should a defendant be able<br />

615

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!