16.11.2012 Views

Wireless Network Design: Optimization Models and Solution ...

Wireless Network Design: Optimization Models and Solution ...

Wireless Network Design: Optimization Models and Solution ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

7 Spectrum Auctions 165<br />

prior round. The set of constraints (7.10) assures that the price paid by each bidder<br />

is bounded below by its VCG price <strong>and</strong> above by its maximum bid price (value).<br />

Based on the prices generated in the above linear optimization problem, one calculates<br />

the discount for bidder j as the difference between the value of the winning<br />

bid <strong>and</strong> the price at this step of the algorithm. All bids of winning bidders are discounted<br />

by this amount <strong>and</strong> the winner determination problem (WDP Core(τ)) is again<br />

re-solved. The process continues until one can find no coalition that can increase<br />

revenue to the seller. This algorithm therefore finds prices for each winning bidder<br />

that are in the core. Since there may be many such minimum core prices, Day <strong>and</strong><br />

Milgrom [18] suggest that one choose - in order to encourage sincere bidding - the<br />

minimum core prices that are closest in Euclidean distance from the VCG prices.<br />

Alternatively, Erdil <strong>and</strong> Klemperer [24] argue for a different set of minimum core<br />

prices that are based “on a class of ’reference rules’ in which bidders’ payments are,<br />

roughly speaking, determined independently of their own bids as far as possible”.<br />

These core-selecting second-price sealed-bid mechanisms are relatively new.<br />

They have the following nice properties: They are in the core; they eliminate the<br />

exposure problem; <strong>and</strong>, they encourage bidders to bid sincerely. As with all sealedbid<br />

auctions, they make collusion <strong>and</strong> punishment for not adhering to tacit agreements<br />

extremely difficult. In 2010, Portugal is scheduled to hold a core-selecting<br />

second-price auction (see announcement on Portuguese website anacom.pt).<br />

There are, however, negatives associated with this auction design in that it puts<br />

a significant burden on the bidders. Each bidder needs to assess for each possible<br />

combination of items whether it is a package that it would like to acquire <strong>and</strong> then,<br />

for those that make sense for the bidder, provide a value for the package. In addition,<br />

such mechanisms do not provide any information about how the packages submitted<br />

might “fit” with packages submitted by other bidders. To overcome these problems,<br />

a number of authors have suggested new package-bidding designs that replicate<br />

many of the features of the simultaneous ascending auction.<br />

7.5.2 Two Combinatorial Ascending Auction <strong>Design</strong>s<br />

7.5.2.1 General Ascending Package-bidding <strong>Design</strong>:<br />

In 2000, the FCC considered a package-bidding auction that resembled the SAA<br />

auction in many respects. It had most of the same rules as the SAA except that it allowed<br />

bidders to submit package bids. Each round a winner determination problem<br />

was solved to determine the winners with the constraint that at most one bid of any<br />

bidder could be in an optimal solution.<br />

In an ascending auction, the auctioneer must announce prices for the next round.<br />

Since packages, rather than individual items may be winning, one needs to be able to<br />

allocate the package price among the individual elements that make up that package.<br />

If one has such individual item prices, then one can determine the price of any new<br />

package as the sum of the items that make up the package. However, since there is

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!