06.09.2021 Views

International Trade - Theory and Policy, 2010a

International Trade - Theory and Policy, 2010a

International Trade - Theory and Policy, 2010a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Import tariff effects on the importing country’s government. The government receives tariff revenue given by<br />

the per-unit tax (t) multiplied by the quantity of imports (QT). Who gains from the tariff revenue depends<br />

on how the government spends the money. Presumably these revenues help support the provision of<br />

public goods or help sustain transfer payments. In either case, someone in the economy ultimately<br />

benefits from the revenue. Refer to Table 9.9 "Welfare Effects of a Tariff" <strong>and</strong> Figure 9.5 "A Tariff on Imports<br />

from a Foreign Monopoly Firm" to see how the magnitude of the subsidy payments is represented.<br />

The aggregate welfare effect for the importing country is found by summing the gains <strong>and</strong> losses to<br />

consumers, producers, <strong>and</strong> the government. The net effect consists of two components: a positive effect<br />

on the recipients of the government tariff revenue (d) <strong>and</strong> a negative effect on consumers (a + b + c), who<br />

lose welfare due to higher prices.<br />

If dem<strong>and</strong> is linear, it is straightforward to show that the gains to the country will always exceed the losses<br />

for some positive nonprohibitive tariff. In other words, there will exist a positive optimal tariff. Thus a<br />

tariff can raise national welfare when the market is supplied by a foreign monopolist.<br />

One reason for this positive effect is that the tariff essentially shifts profits away from the foreign<br />

monopolist to the domestic government. Note that the original profit level is given by the large blue<br />

rectangle shown in Figure 9.5 "A Tariff on Imports from a Foreign Monopoly Firm". When the tariff is<br />

implemented, the monopolist’s profit falls to a level given by the red rectangle. Thus, in this case, the tariff<br />

raises aggregate domestic welfare as it reduces the foreign firm’s profit.<br />

First-Best <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Although a tariff can raise national welfare in this case, it is not the first-best policy to correct the market<br />

imperfection. A first-best policy must attack the imperfection more directly. In this case, the imperfection<br />

is the monopolistic supply of the product to the market. A monopoly maximizes profit by choosing an<br />

output level such that marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. This rule deviates from what a perfectly<br />

competitive firm would do—that is, set price equal to marginal cost. When a firm is one among many, it<br />

must take the price as given. It cannot influence the price by changing its output level. In this case, the<br />

price is its marginal revenue. However, for a monopolist, which can influence the market price, price<br />

exceeds marginal revenue. Thus when the monopolist maximizes profit, it sets a price greater than<br />

marginal cost. This deviation—that is, P > MC—is at the core of the market imperfection.<br />

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books<br />

Saylor.org<br />

479

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!