06.09.2021 Views

International Trade - Theory and Policy, 2010a

International Trade - Theory and Policy, 2010a

International Trade - Theory and Policy, 2010a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

elieves that it would be very difficult to raise domestic production rapidly in the event that imported<br />

products were ever cut off, as might occur during a war. In this case, a government may decide that its<br />

imports are too high <strong>and</strong> thus pose a threat to the country’s national security.<br />

A natural response in this instance is to put high tariffs in place to prevent imports from crowding out<br />

domestic production. Surely, a tariff exists that will reduce imports to 10 percent <strong>and</strong> subsequently cause<br />

domestic production to rise to 90 percent. We know from tariff analysis that in the case of a small country,<br />

a tariff will cause a net welfare loss for the nation in a perfectly competitive market. These same gains <strong>and</strong><br />

losses <strong>and</strong> net welfare effects can be expected to prevail here. However, because of the presence of the<br />

public good characteristics of national security, there is more to the story. Although the tariff alone causes<br />

a net welfare loss for the economy, the effect is offset with a positive benefit to the nation in the form of<br />

greater security. If the added security adds more to national welfare than the economic losses caused by<br />

the tariff, then overall national welfare will rise. Thus protectionism can be beneficial for the country.<br />

The national security argument for protection is perfectly valid <strong>and</strong> sound. It is perfectly logical under<br />

these conditions that protectionism can improve the nation’s welfare. However, because of the theory of<br />

the second best, many economists remain opposed to the use of protectionism, even in these<br />

circumstances. The reason is that protectionism turns out to be a second-best policy option.<br />

Recall that the first-best policy response to a market imperfection is a policy that is targeted as directly as<br />

possible at the imperfection itself. Thus, if the imperfection arises because of some production<br />

characteristic, a production subsidy or tax should be used. If the problem is in the labor market, a tax or<br />

subsidy in that market would be best, <strong>and</strong> if the market imperfection is associated with international<br />

trade, then a trade policy should be used.<br />

In this case, one might argue that the problem is trade related, since one can say that national security is<br />

diminished because there are too many imports of, say, agricultural goods. Thus an import tariff should<br />

be used. However, this logic is wrong. The actual problem is maintaining an adequate food supply in a<br />

time of war. The problem is really a production problem because if imports were to be cut off in an<br />

emergency, the level of production would be too low. The most cost-effective way, in this situation, to<br />

maintain production at adequate levels will be a production subsidy. The production subsidy will raise<br />

domestic production of the good <strong>and</strong> can be set high enough to assure that an adequate quantity is<br />

produced each year. The subsidy will cost the government money <strong>and</strong> it will generate a net production<br />

Saylor URL: http://www.saylor.org/books<br />

Saylor.org<br />

492

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!