23.01.2015 Views

Hope Not Hype - Third World Network

Hope Not Hype - Third World Network

Hope Not Hype - Third World Network

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

106 <strong>Hope</strong> <strong>Not</strong> <strong>Hype</strong><br />

From new drugs to better seeds, the best of the new technologies are priced for those who can<br />

pay. For poor people, they remain far out of reach (UNDP, 1999, p. 6).<br />

The consolidation of the seed industry has been led by the agrochemical companies<br />

which are rapidly converting into biotechnology companies as a result of IPR law changes.<br />

The large multinational agro-chemical companies were the early investors in the development<br />

of [transgenic cotton, corn, canola, and soybean] crops. One of the reasons that agro-chemical<br />

companies got into the act was that they foresaw a declining market for pesticides. The chemical<br />

companies got a quick start in the plant improvement business by purchasing existing seed<br />

companies, first in industrialized countries and then in the developing world…Acquisitions<br />

also represented an efficient means of obtaining the smaller firms’ intellectual property and<br />

know-how, much simpler than replication or ‘inventing around’ it. The industry can now be<br />

characterized by a few ‘mega-firms’, with combined capabilities in biotechnology,<br />

agrochemicals, and seeds (Pingali and Traxler, 2002, p. 227).<br />

The private sector in developed countries outspends the public on agricultural<br />

innovation 55% to 45%, with the top six agrochemical/biotechnology companies spending<br />

US$3.5 billion, or eight times the research budget of the Consultative Group on International<br />

Agricultural Research (CGIAR) system (Spielman, 2007). The combination of agricultural<br />

innovation shifting to the “mega-corporations”, and the appropriability made possible<br />

through the unprecedented changes in IPR laws, is altering long-term and successful<br />

agricultural practices and farmers’ rights such as seed saving, while threatening long-term<br />

sustainability of agricultural innovation coming from both the private and public sectors.<br />

The Assessment came to agree that:<br />

Much of the economics discussion of agricultural R&D and agricultural R&D policy refers<br />

to the public goods nature of agricultural R&D, and the market failures associated with the<br />

reliance on private provision. It would seem to follow that the natural solution is for the<br />

government to intervene to correct the market failure by providing agricultural R&D, like<br />

other public goods, financed by general government revenues. Such analysis and prescription<br />

is too simple, however, because most forms of agricultural R&D are not pure public goods;<br />

and, consequently, other interventions may be fairer, more effective, or more efficient ways<br />

to correct problems of underinvestment (Pardey et al., 2007, p. 38).<br />

To achieve a path where investment in agricultural innovation follows the needs of<br />

the majority, there will have to be systematic and far-ranging changes. These must extend<br />

well beyond tinkering with IPR laws. The changes will require that trade policies and<br />

subsidies be the subject of major renovation. The details of trade policy revision are beyond<br />

the scope of this book. What will be discussed below are the immediate prevailing costs of<br />

the current and growing concentration of legal and economic power in the megacorporations.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!