03.07.2013 Views

Conference Sessions - Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of ...

Conference Sessions - Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of ...

Conference Sessions - Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

TC01 MARKETING SCIENCE CONFERENCE – 2011<br />

2 - Conspicuous Consumption and Dynamic Pricing<br />

Richard Schaefer, PhD Student, University <strong>of</strong> Texas at Austin,<br />

1 University Station, B6700, McCombs <strong>School</strong> <strong>of</strong> Business,<br />

Austin, TX, 78703, United States <strong>of</strong> America,<br />

Richard.Schaefer@phd.mccombs.utexas.edu, Raghunath Rao<br />

We study a producer’s dynamic pricing policy when marketing a durable good,<br />

particularly an item that provides consumer utility via two mechanisms; specifically,<br />

consumers experience an intrinsic consumption utility and an externality (denoted<br />

‘fashion utility’) that depends upon the conspicuousness <strong>of</strong> the product and the<br />

identity <strong>of</strong> other consumers <strong>of</strong> using the same product.In our analytical model, we<br />

consider the joint impact <strong>of</strong> consumption utility and fashion utility, and our results<br />

reverse the direction <strong>of</strong> causality long emphasized in prior studies. We show that<br />

products with high intrinsic quality command higher prices due to greater input costs;<br />

with a higher retail price, such products become exclusive and, hence, more<br />

fashionable when consumption is visible. Two key results emerge from the analysis <strong>of</strong><br />

our dynamic model: a) whether the producer sells its product via skimming over time<br />

depends upon the discount factor, and b) under skimming, more visible products<br />

depreciate faster. We extend our model to study the investments that producer might<br />

make to separate the cohorts over time and thereby not dilute the intertemporal<br />

fashion utility for the early adopters <strong>of</strong> the product. We find that a producer will be<br />

willing to incur higher costs for cohort separation if the product visibility is higher but<br />

would decrease this investment if the product is higher in intrinsic quality, all else<br />

being equal. The results <strong>of</strong> our paper are <strong>of</strong> potential interest to manufacturers <strong>of</strong><br />

fashion goods for their pricing strategies as well as to the policy makers for studying<br />

the welfare impact <strong>of</strong> identity-related goods that have <strong>of</strong>ten been derided for<br />

providing very few intrinsic benefits.<br />

3 - Estimating Dynamic Pricing Decisions in Markets with State<br />

Dependent Demand<br />

Koray Cosguner, PhD Student in Marketing, Washington University in<br />

St. Louis, Olin Business <strong>School</strong>, Campus Box 1133, Saint Louis, MO,<br />

63130, United States <strong>of</strong> America, cosgunerk@wustl.edu,<br />

Tat Y. Chan, P. B. Seetharaman<br />

We propose an empirical approach to examine the pricing behavior <strong>of</strong> manufacturers<br />

in the presence <strong>of</strong> state dependent demand. To the extent that state dependence<br />

characterizes the evolution <strong>of</strong> brands’ market shares, pr<strong>of</strong>it maximizing firms should<br />

consider these inter-temporal linkages in demand and be forward-looking in their<br />

pricing decisions. In this study, we estimate such a dynamic pricing model <strong>of</strong> firms.<br />

First, we propose a demand model with state dependence and estimate it by using<br />

household scanner panel data. This demand model is inputted into our fully<br />

structural dynamic pricing model that we use to estimate the marginal costs <strong>of</strong> each<br />

firm in the industry studied. We use approaches proposed by Berry and Pakes (2000)<br />

and Bajari, Benkard and Levin (2007) to estimate this dynamic pricing model. Before<br />

estimating the dynamic pricing model by using store level data, we perform a<br />

simulation study by using Pakes and McGuire (1994) algorithm. This study allows us<br />

to check the performance <strong>of</strong> Berry and Pakes (2000) and Bajari, Benkard and Levin<br />

(2007) approaches in terms <strong>of</strong> recovering the assumed structural parameters <strong>of</strong><br />

interest. Then, we estimate the marginal costs <strong>of</strong> each firm in the cola product<br />

category by using our proposed dynamic pricing model and compare our estimates<br />

with the estimates from two benchmark cases: myopic (maximizing single period<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>it) and static pricing models (demand without state dependence). Our framework<br />

not only helps firms to understand the demand dynamics in the industry, but also<br />

helps them to make their pricing decisions optimally. Furthermore, the proposed<br />

framework can be used by new potential entrants, incumbent firms or regulators to<br />

understand the cost structure in any oligopolistic market.<br />

4 - Dynamic Targeted Pricing in B2B Settings<br />

Jonathan Zhang, Assistant Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> Marketing, University <strong>of</strong><br />

Washington, 547 Paccar Hall Box 353226, Seattle, WA, 98195,<br />

United States <strong>of</strong> America, zaozao@uw.edu, Oded Netzer,<br />

Asim Ansari<br />

This research models the impact <strong>of</strong> firm pricing decisions on different facets <strong>of</strong> the<br />

customer purchasing process in business-to-business (B2B) contexts and develops an<br />

integrated framework for inter-temporal targeted pricing to maximize long-term<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itability for the firm. B2B pricing <strong>of</strong>ten allows considerable flexibility in<br />

implementing first degree and inter-temporal price discrimination, and <strong>of</strong>ten involve<br />

a request for a price quote providing the firm with an opportunity to better assess<br />

price sensitivity and unfulfilled demand. The proposed model considers the buyer’s<br />

quantity, timing and bid request and acceptance decisions in an integrated fashion<br />

while accounting for customer heterogeneity, asymmetric reference price effects, and<br />

short- and long-term purchase dynamics. We weave together hierarchical Bayesian<br />

copulas with a non-homogeneous hidden Markov model to account for the interrelated<br />

decisions and for long-term purchase dynamics. The results reveal that the<br />

seller’s pricing decisions can have long-term impact on its buyers by shifting their<br />

preferences between a “vigilant” and “relaxed” buying state, Furthermore, price losses<br />

relative to a reference price not only have larger negative effects relative to gains on<br />

buyers’ buying behavior, but buyers also take longer to adapt to losses. Additionally,<br />

the proposed model exhibits superior predictive performance relative to benchmark<br />

models. In a price policy simulation the proposed model results in a 52%<br />

improvement in pr<strong>of</strong>itability, demonstrating the potential to employ value-based<br />

pricing policies even in a traditional B2B industry characterized by cost-plus pricing<br />

practices. Other policy simulations shed light on how B2B firm should price in the<br />

recent economic environment with volatile commodity prices.<br />

18<br />

Thursday, 1:30pm - 3:00pm<br />

■ TC01<br />

Legends Ballroom I<br />

Choice I: New Models <strong>of</strong> …<br />

Contributed Session<br />

Chair: Peter Stuettgen, Carnegie Mellon University, 5000 Forbes Ave.,<br />

Pittsburgh, PA, 15213, United States <strong>of</strong> America,<br />

pstuettg@andrew.cmu.edu<br />

1 - Assessing Two Alternative Methods for Modelling Heterogeneity in<br />

Stated Preference Data<br />

Paul Wang, Senior Lecturer, University <strong>of</strong> Technology, Sydney,<br />

Marketing Discipline Group, P.O. Box 123, Sydney, Australia,<br />

Paul.Wang@uts.edu.au, Jordan Louviere, Kyuseop Kwak<br />

Market segmentation has long been recognized as one <strong>of</strong> the key concepts in the<br />

marketing discipline (e.g., Frank et al. 1972; Wedel and Kamakura 2000). It refers to<br />

the process <strong>of</strong> classifying customers into homogeneous groups known as segments.<br />

Stated choice experiment (aka choice-based conjoint analysis) <strong>of</strong>fers a more powerful<br />

method to obtain customer preference data than traditional rating method (Louviere<br />

et al. 2000; Street et al. 2005). Stated choice models based on the random utility<br />

framework are becoming increasingly popular in marketing and applied economics<br />

literature (Louviere et al. 2000; Train 2009). The need to account for preference<br />

heterogeneity in such models has motivated researchers to develop various ways to<br />

solve the problem. Most commonly, researchers make a certain distributional<br />

assumption for unknown heterogeneity across respondents and across choice tasks. If<br />

a continuous distribution is assumed, mixed logit (Train 2009) or hierarchical<br />

Bayesian approaches (Rossi et al. 2005) are used to approximate such unobserved<br />

heterogeneity. If a discrete distribution is assumed, latent class model is mostly used<br />

(Kamakura and Russell 1989) to identify latent market segments. The primary<br />

purpose <strong>of</strong> this paper is to introduce two alternative methods for modeling preference<br />

heterogeneity in stated choice data: (1) Cutler and Breiman’s (1994) archetypal<br />

analysis method and (2) Kaufman and Rousseeuw’s (1990) fuzzy analysis clustering<br />

method. We compare these less well-known ways <strong>of</strong> incorporating preference<br />

heterogeneity with the traditional latent class modeling approach using health carerelated<br />

choice data. We find the two alternative methods have considerable promise<br />

for strategic market segmentation applications.<br />

2 - A Direct Utility Model for Asymmetric Complements<br />

Sanghak Lee, The Ohio State University, 2100 Neil Ave, Columbus,<br />

43210, United States <strong>of</strong> America, lee_3121@fisher.osu.edu,<br />

Greg Allenby, Jaehwan Kim<br />

Asymmetric complements refer to goods where one is more dependent on the other,<br />

yet consumers receive enhanced utility from consuming both. Examples include<br />

garden hoses and sprinklers, chips and dip, and routine versus personalized services<br />

where the former has a broader base for utility generation and the latter is more<br />

dependent on the other’s presence. Measuring the presence <strong>of</strong> asymmetries is difficult<br />

because it requires longitudinal variation <strong>of</strong> utility where the degree <strong>of</strong> interdependency<br />

changes. We introduce a utility structure capable <strong>of</strong> identifying the origin<br />

<strong>of</strong> demand variation, and investigate the presence <strong>of</strong> asymmetric complementarity<br />

using scanner panel data <strong>of</strong> milk, cereal, ketchup, and yogurt purchases. Implications<br />

are explored through counterfactual analyses involving price elasticities, spillover<br />

effects and the influence <strong>of</strong> merchandising variables.<br />

3 - Utility-based Model <strong>of</strong> Asymmetric Competitive Structure using<br />

Store-level and Forced Switching Data<br />

Paul Messinger, University <strong>of</strong> Alberta, 3-23 Business Building,<br />

Edmonton, Canada, paul.messinger@ualberta.ca, Fang Wu<br />

We propose a utility-based model <strong>of</strong> competitive structure that accounts for and<br />

spatially represents both vertical (quality) and horizontal characteristics, where we<br />

show how the vertical characteristics govern observed asymmetric substitution<br />

patterns in the data. We find it desirable to estimate our model jointly with two kinds<br />

<strong>of</strong> data, aggregate store-level sales data and forced switching survey (stated<br />

preference) data. To facilitate estimation with such two kinds <strong>of</strong> data, we develop a<br />

behavioral justification that establishes a conceptual linkage between these two kinds<br />

<strong>of</strong> data. The intuition idea behind our modeling approach is that consumers’ actual<br />

purchase behavior for brands gives us important market structure information<br />

regarding brands’ proximities in some latent attribute space, and the same proximity<br />

relationships across brands influence the consumers’ forced switching behavior. By<br />

imposing a particular distribution on latent ideal points and willingness to pay<br />

parameters, we are able to estimate heterogeneity in our proposed model.<br />

4 - A Satisficing Choice Model<br />

Peter Stuettgen, Carnegie Mellon University, 5000 Forbes Ave.,<br />

Pittsburgh, PA, 15213, United States <strong>of</strong> America,<br />

pstuettg@andrew.cmu.edu, Peter Boatwright, Robert Monroe<br />

In addition to the standard compensatory choice models like logit and probit models,<br />

a new stream <strong>of</strong> research has recently proposed several non-compensatory choice<br />

models, most <strong>of</strong> them variants <strong>of</strong> the conjunctive choice rule (e.g., Gilbride and<br />

Allenby 2004, Jedidi and Kohli 2005). We contribute to this new stream by<br />

formulating a consumer choice model based on Simon’s (1955) idea <strong>of</strong> “satisficing”<br />

decision making, in which alternatives are evaluated sequentially and the first<br />

satisfactory alternative is chosen. This requires knowledge (or probabilistic modeling)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!