03.07.2013 Views

Conference Sessions - Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of ...

Conference Sessions - Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of ...

Conference Sessions - Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

4 - Green Lifestyle Adoption: Shopping Without Plastic Bags<br />

Wenbo Wang, PhD Candidate, New York University,<br />

40 West 4th Street, Room 921, New York, NY, 10012,<br />

United States <strong>of</strong> America, wwang2@stern.nyu.edu, Yuxin Chen<br />

This research develops a structural model <strong>of</strong> consumer lifestyle adoption. The model<br />

captures two behavioral features —- forward looking and accessibility contingency —<br />

- that are shared by many lifestyles. Lifestyle adoption <strong>of</strong>ten involves a deliberate<br />

trade-<strong>of</strong>f between long-term benefit and extra effort at the initial stage, and therefore<br />

motivates consumers to look forward in adoption decisions. Moreover, the forward<br />

looking adoption is contingent on accessibility <strong>of</strong> the optimal lifestyle choice. For<br />

instance, even though one intends to lives a healthy lifestyle, he may accidentally<br />

forget to bring sneakers from time to time. In this case, the gym exercise lifestyle<br />

choice is not accessible to him at the decision moment. Inaccessibility can occur due<br />

to, for example, memory limitations or cognitive constraints. We estimate the model<br />

with a panel data <strong>of</strong> a green lifestyle adoption <strong>of</strong> urban shoppers under the plastic bag<br />

ban in China. The ban is lifestyle-changing to the consumers because they now have<br />

to either bring own shopping bags or pay for plastic bags. This research sheds light on<br />

the following questions: 1) How does accessibility contingency interplay with forward<br />

looking in the green lifestyle adoption? 2) What is the role <strong>of</strong> state dependence on<br />

the lifestyle adoption? 3) How long does it take a shopper to stabilize on the new<br />

green lifestyle and where is the no-return point for this lifestyle? 4) How can<br />

marketing mix decisions facilitate the adoption?<br />

■ FC05<br />

Legends Ballroom VI<br />

Game Theory II: Market Entry<br />

Contributed Session<br />

Chair: Matthew Selove, Assistant Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> Marketing, USC Marshall<br />

<strong>School</strong> <strong>of</strong> Business, 3660 Trousdale Parkway, ACC 306E, Los Angeles, CA,<br />

90089, United States <strong>of</strong> America, selove@marshall.usc.edu<br />

1 - Cross-market Experience and Market Entry<br />

Dai Yao, PhD Student, INSEAD, PhD Room (2nd floor),<br />

1 Ayer Rajah Avenue, INSEAD, Singapore, 138676, Singapore,<br />

dai.yao@insead.edu, Yakov Bart<br />

Cross-market experience externality arises when a firm may choose to provide<br />

products or services in one market in order to gain experience that could benefit<br />

launching products or services in another market. Examples <strong>of</strong> industries with such<br />

externality include IT outsourcing market vs. IT consulting market and PC<br />

components market vs. PC market.Multi-market environments that exhibit such<br />

cross-market experience externalities are structurally different from industries in<br />

which multiple markets are related to each other through characteristics <strong>of</strong> goods. We<br />

propose a game-theoretic model toprovide explanations to different patterns in<br />

regards to optimal entry time for market entrants and optimal defending strategies for<br />

market incumbents in such multi-market environments.Our analysis characterizes<br />

the impact <strong>of</strong> cross-market experience externalities on firms’ optimal market entry<br />

decisions and competitive interactions.<br />

2 - The Benefit <strong>of</strong> Increased Competition<br />

David Soberman, Canadian National Chair in Strategic Marketing,<br />

Rotman <strong>School</strong> <strong>of</strong> Management, University <strong>of</strong> Toronto,<br />

105 St. George Street, Toronto, Ontario, Canada,<br />

david.soberman@rotman.utoronto.ca, Amit Pazgal<br />

We consider a fundamental question regarding the need for incumbents to protect<br />

their turf and foreclose entry to their industry. This has been a fundamental issue <strong>of</strong><br />

industrial organization for more than 50 years (Bain 1956) and numerous studies<br />

have demonstrated how barriers to entry are used to protect and increase pr<strong>of</strong>its. But<br />

are there times when a new entrant can be beneficial for incumbent firms?<br />

Sometimes late entrants learn from incumbents and are able to improve on existing<br />

<strong>of</strong>ferings. However, late entrants are also known to <strong>of</strong>fer stripped down versions <strong>of</strong><br />

products that have reduced functionality. Using a spatial model, we demonstrate that<br />

a stripped down new entrant can lead to higher (and not lower) incumbent pr<strong>of</strong>its by<br />

capturing a quality insensitive/price sensitive segment <strong>of</strong> consumers that are the<br />

source <strong>of</strong> intense competition between incumbents. This can create a win-win<br />

situation for all competitors including the entrant. Our analysis identifies the precise<br />

conditions where this occurs and also conditions where incumbents should seek to<br />

blockade the potential entrant.<br />

3 - A Dynamic Model <strong>of</strong> Competitive Entry Response<br />

Matthew Selove, Assistant Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> Marketing, USC Marshall<br />

<strong>School</strong> <strong>of</strong> Business, 3660 Trousdale Parkway, ACC 306E,<br />

Los Angeles, CA, 90089, United States <strong>of</strong> America,<br />

selove@marshall.usc.edu<br />

This paper develops a model in which competing firms invest in various business<br />

formats. For example, they could implement full service or “no-frills” airline models. I<br />

derive conditions in which each firm specializes in a single format, and conditions in<br />

which both firms adopt both formats. In some cases, increased difficulty <strong>of</strong><br />

implementing a format increases the likelihood that firms attack each other by<br />

investing in each other’s format. This is because barriers to entry also serve as barriers<br />

to retaliation, allowing firms to attack without fear <strong>of</strong> swift punishment.<br />

MARKETING SCIENCE CONFERENCE – 2011 FC06<br />

55<br />

■ FC06<br />

Legends Ballroom VII<br />

Channels III: Competition<br />

Contributed Session<br />

Chair: Jaime Romero, Associate Pr<strong>of</strong>essor, University Autonoma Madrid,<br />

Fac. CC. Económicas, Avda. Tomas y Valiente, 5, Madrid, 28049, Spain,<br />

jaime.romero@uam.es<br />

1 - When and How Do Coordinating Contracts Improve<br />

Channel Efficiency?<br />

Ernan Haruvy, Associate Pr<strong>of</strong>essor, Universiy <strong>of</strong> Texas at Dallas,<br />

800 West Campbell Rd, Richardson, TX, 75080,<br />

United States <strong>of</strong> America, eharuvy@utdallas.edu<br />

A growing literature shows that coordinating contracts may not improve efficiency in<br />

the laboratory to the extent prescribed by theory. We show that this result is largely<br />

due to <strong>of</strong>fer rejection where the bargaining procedure is structured as an ultimatum<br />

<strong>of</strong>fer, which is the only structure studied in the lab hitherto in relation to<br />

coordinating contracts. We show that a less restrictive procedure does not involve this<br />

feature and allows coordinating contracts to coordinate. Specifically, we look at three<br />

contract formats – wholesale price, two-part-tariff and minimum order quantity. The<br />

wholesale price leads to loss <strong>of</strong> firm surplus because <strong>of</strong> double marginalization. The<br />

other two contracts – the coordinating contracts – allow the manufacturer to<br />

coordinate the channel, either by pricing at cost and extracting surplus through a<br />

lump sum payment (two part tariff) or through announcing a minimum order<br />

quantity which is equal to the efficient quantity and extracting the surplus through<br />

price (minimum order quantity contract). Even though for fully rational players these<br />

two coordinating contracts are equivalent, these two contracts are different under<br />

mild bounded rationality assumptions. Proposals in the minimum order quantity<br />

treatment are far more efficient than two-part-tariff proposals in terms <strong>of</strong> the overall<br />

surplus they imply. But in the ultimatum context such efficient proposals tend to get<br />

rejected, leading to lower ex-post efficiency. With structured negotiations bargaining,<br />

however, rejection rate drastically falls leading to a more direct relationship between<br />

proposal efficiency and ex-post efficiency.<br />

2 - Channel Structure and Performance under Co-marketing Alliance<br />

Xiao Zuhui, The Hong Kong Polytechnic University, Room 409, New<br />

East Ocean Centre, 9 Science Museum Road, Honghum,<br />

Hong Kong, Hong Kong - PRC, zuhuixiao@msn.com, Liu Liming,<br />

Zhang Xubing<br />

A growing number <strong>of</strong> companies are seeking cooperation to better serve their clients.<br />

Among various types <strong>of</strong> cooperative strategies, lateral relationships between firms at<br />

the same level in the value chain, are popular in both good and service markets. In<br />

these relations, downstream firms jointly market the products or provide value add<br />

service for upstream suppliers to increase pr<strong>of</strong>it and promote sales. Although<br />

introducing marketing effort from a third party has become more common in<br />

business life, this type <strong>of</strong> cooperation receives little continuing attention in the<br />

literature. Motivated by real business cases, we aim to provide a better understanding<br />

on how these cooperative activities create values for partnering firms and their<br />

common clients. We construct models for marketing and channel decisions <strong>of</strong> alliance<br />

partners under different scenarios. Our modeling analysis focuses on the following<br />

issues: (1) how the firms involved make their individual decisions in equilibrium; (2)<br />

how different cooperation structures influence the performance <strong>of</strong> firms involved; (3)<br />

how market conditions, i.e., demand uncertainty and asymmetric information,<br />

influence the firms’ performance. We characterize the different scenarios in these<br />

settings, providing conditions under which the cooperation structure will benefit the<br />

partnering firms. We show that, under certain market conditions, the partnering<br />

firms and even total channel may be better <strong>of</strong>f under these cooperative activities.<br />

3 - Should be Close to or Away from Your Competitors? Store Location<br />

Choice by Gravity Model<br />

Wei-Jhih Yang, PhD Candidate, National Taiwan University, No.1, Sec.<br />

4, Roosevelt Rd., Taipei City, Taiwan - ROC, flieryang@gmail.com,<br />

Jesheng Huang, Lichung Jen<br />

Agglomeration among competing firms in store location cluster may enlarge<br />

consumer demand, but may also create more brand competitive intensity in<br />

consumer’s mind spontaneously. From managerial perspective, it is hard to identify<br />

who made much more efforts and who should gain more if the economies <strong>of</strong><br />

agglomeration exist; likewise, it’s also difficult to examine who would threat others<br />

and who won’t if the diseconomies <strong>of</strong> agglomeration exist. More specifically, for<br />

channel strategy, a firm’s store should be close to or away from the agglomeration <strong>of</strong><br />

its competitors? And for brand positioning strategy, how a firm can get a good<br />

location in consumer’s mind to avoid the points <strong>of</strong> parity. Therefore, how to address<br />

this kind <strong>of</strong> dual competitive intensities is the focus <strong>of</strong> this article. Based on the<br />

concept <strong>of</strong> gravity model from physics, the authors propose a location gravity model<br />

to analyze why a firm should close to or away from its competitors. The authors<br />

firstly use consumers’ brand perceptual mapping to measure the cognitive distance <strong>of</strong><br />

the competing brands in an agglomeration through MDS; then, the results <strong>of</strong><br />

cognitive distance among competing brands will be applied to location gravity model,<br />

in order to calculate distribution intensity in the spatial cluster formed by a firm and<br />

the agglomeration <strong>of</strong> its competitors. Based on the proposed model which combining<br />

both considerations <strong>of</strong> dual competition intensities , the authors suggest how a firm<br />

can choose the optimal store location which may avoid the exiting competition from<br />

the cluster <strong>of</strong> store locations and get the best position in consumers’ mind. Finally the<br />

authors discuss the managerial implications <strong>of</strong> this model for the blue ocean strategy.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!