03.07.2013 Views

Conference Sessions - Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of ...

Conference Sessions - Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of ...

Conference Sessions - Jesse H. Jones Graduate School of ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

3 - Which Link to Click – Sponsored or Organic? An Empirical<br />

Investigation on Consumer’s ‘Clickability’<br />

Amalesh Sharma, Teaching Associate, Indian <strong>School</strong> <strong>of</strong> Business,<br />

Gachibowli, Hyderabad, 500032, India, amaleshsharma@gmail.com,<br />

Sourav Borah<br />

Sponsored search advertising has arguably become the most predominant form <strong>of</strong><br />

advertising in the online marketing strategy. Sponsored links are paid links and<br />

organic links are natural or non-paid links. Prior research has studied the relation<br />

between organic and sponsored search advertisement, click process and clicking time<br />

(Chatterjee, H<strong>of</strong>fman, Novak 2003), browsing behavior <strong>of</strong> customers in multi-site<br />

context (Park and Fader 2004) and online media selection (Danahar, Lee and<br />

Kerbache 2009). Montgomery et al (2004) model online browsing behavior to predict<br />

buying behavior <strong>of</strong> customers. In this research we study which specific link in a webpage<br />

is clicked on in a consumer search algorithm and why. An extended<br />

understanding on the clickability can open up advanced research area in online<br />

marketing literature and help to capture the dynamics in the market. We also try to<br />

understand the drivers for such click-ability. For this, we build an integrated model<br />

using a hierarchical Bayesian Framework to develop a relationship among factors<br />

such as keywords findings, key-word appropriateness to the search, nature <strong>of</strong> search<br />

(information/general), display <strong>of</strong> the link, rank <strong>of</strong> the link and previous history if any.<br />

Our data comes from a controlled field experiments conducted in India. Our results<br />

indicate that browsers click relatively more on the organic link (a counter finding<br />

from the earlier researches on clickability). We also predict that our findings will<br />

provide critical insight to the practitioners in determining where to place the name <strong>of</strong><br />

the organization in web page and whether to go for paid advertisements.<br />

4 - Predicting Purchase Conversion Rates for Online Search<br />

Advertisements Using Text Mining<br />

Alan Montgomery, Associate Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> Marketing, Carnegie Mellon<br />

University, 5000 Forbes Avenue, Pittsburgh, PA, 15213, United States<br />

<strong>of</strong> America, alan.montgomery@cmu.edu, Kinshuk Jerath, Qihang Lin<br />

Many consumers begin their purchase process at search engines such as Google,<br />

Yahoo, or MSN instead <strong>of</strong> traditional retailers. Consumers rely upon the search<br />

results provided by these engines along with paid advertising to make decisions about<br />

what sites to visit and subsequently which products to purchase. In this study we<br />

propose a statistical model that predicts consumer search and the probability <strong>of</strong><br />

purchase using clickstream data collected from an online sample <strong>of</strong> consumers. A<br />

challenge in analyzing this data is the textual nature <strong>of</strong> the search strings and the<br />

scarcity <strong>of</strong> many search terms. We also consider how consumers will search based<br />

upon the specificity <strong>of</strong> the search term. This model is cast in the context <strong>of</strong> a<br />

hierarchical Bayesian model to overcome the limited information for many search<br />

strings and consumers. We illustrate how this model can be used to aid advertisers in<br />

making decisions about how much to bid, what phrase to bid upon, and the<br />

appropriate landing page for the consumer once they enter the web site.<br />

■ FD04<br />

Legends Ballroom V<br />

Structural Models II<br />

Contributed Session<br />

Chair: Yi Zhao, Georgia State University, Suite 1300, 35 Broad Street,<br />

Atlanta, GA, 30303, United States <strong>of</strong> America, yizhao@gsu.edu<br />

1 - The Impact <strong>of</strong> the Marketing Mix on Durable Product<br />

Replacement Decisions<br />

Dinakar Jayarajan, Doctoral Candidate, USC Marshall, 3660 Trousdale<br />

Pkwy, ACC 306E, Los Angeles, CA, 90089, United States <strong>of</strong> America,<br />

jayaraja@usc.edu, S. Siddarth, Jorge Silva-Risso<br />

Product replacements account for more than 65% <strong>of</strong> sales in durable goods categories<br />

(Fernandez, 2000). Therefore, buying a new durable product effectively involves two<br />

consumer decisions: a) the decision to replace an existing product, and b) the choice<br />

<strong>of</strong> a specific new alternative. The prior literature has analyzed these decisions<br />

separately (e.g., Rust (1987); Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995)), but not jointly,<br />

and has typically ignored the impact <strong>of</strong> marketing activities on these decisions. We<br />

develop a dis-aggregate dynamic structural model <strong>of</strong> the replacement and brand<br />

choice decisions with a forward-looking consumer who forms expectations <strong>of</strong> future<br />

new product prices and promotions. On each purchase opportunity the consumer<br />

trades <strong>of</strong>f retaining the current product with buying a new product based on the<br />

current and expected future utilities <strong>of</strong> the existing and new vehicles available in the<br />

market. We estimate the model using the Nested Fixed Point (NFXP) approach on<br />

automobile transaction data for the entry-level SUV category. We start with a sample<br />

<strong>of</strong> consumers who purchased a new car in 2006 and also traded-in an old one. We<br />

work backwards from this point and reconstruct the monthly marketing environment<br />

for the new products and the monthly depreciation for the traded-in vehicle for up to<br />

eight years. We perform counter-factual analysis to a) examine the extent to which<br />

consumers anticipate promotions b) decompose the impact <strong>of</strong> a promotion on<br />

replacement acceleration and brand switching and c) gain insights into the differences<br />

in the depreciation rate <strong>of</strong> different vehicles.<br />

MARKETING SCIENCE CONFERENCE – 2011 FD04<br />

63<br />

2 - Economic Value <strong>of</strong> Celebrity Endorsement: Tiger Woods’ Impact on<br />

Sales <strong>of</strong> Nike Golf Balls<br />

Kevin Chung, Doctoral Student, Carnegie Mellon University Tepper,<br />

5000 Forbes Avenue, Office 317B GSIA, Pittsburgh, PA, 15221, United<br />

States <strong>of</strong> America, kevinchung@cmu.edu, Timothy Derdenger,<br />

Kannan Srinivasan<br />

In this paper, we study the economic value <strong>of</strong> celebrity endorsements. Despite the<br />

size and the long history <strong>of</strong> the industry, few have attempted to quantify the<br />

economic worth <strong>of</strong> celebrity endorsers because it is terribly difficult to identify an<br />

endorser’s effect on a firm’s pr<strong>of</strong>it. By developing and estimating the consumer<br />

demand model for the golf ball market, we find that after controlling for brand<br />

advertisement level and taking into account the inherent quality <strong>of</strong> the endorser,<br />

there is a significant endorsement effect as a result <strong>of</strong> the extra utility attached to the<br />

endorsed product. This extra utility leads not only to a significant number <strong>of</strong> existing<br />

customers switching toward the endorsed products but also has a primary demand<br />

effect where there is an overall increase in the number <strong>of</strong> consumers in the market.<br />

By sponsoring Tiger Woods for 10 years, we find that the Nike golf ball division<br />

reaped additional pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>of</strong> $60 million through the acquisition <strong>of</strong> 4.5 million<br />

customers who switched as a result <strong>of</strong> the endorsement. We also find that the recent<br />

scandal regarding Tiger Woods’ infidelity had a negative impact which resulted in<br />

Nike losing approximately $1.3 million in pr<strong>of</strong>it with a loss <strong>of</strong> 105,000 customers.<br />

However, we conclude that Nike’s decision to stand by Tiger Woods was the right<br />

decision because even in the midst <strong>of</strong> the negative impact <strong>of</strong> the scandal, had they<br />

terminated its contract with the golfer, Nike would have lost an additional $1.6<br />

million in pr<strong>of</strong>it.<br />

3 - Determination <strong>of</strong> Brand Assortment: An Empirical Entry Game with<br />

Post-choice Outcome<br />

Li Wang, PhD Student, Washington University in St Louis, Olin<br />

Business <strong>School</strong>, Campus Box 1133, Saint Louis, MO, 63130, United<br />

States <strong>of</strong> America, wangli1@wustl.edu, Tat Y. Chan, Alvin Murphy<br />

This paper studies the two-sided decision <strong>of</strong> brands’ entry into a large department<br />

store. This is a two-sided decision process because an observed brand entry has to be<br />

agreed by both department store and the brand. By contrast, in standard entry model<br />

the entry decision is only one-sided as each agent can make such decision alone. We<br />

assume that the store <strong>of</strong>fers each potential entering brand an optimal contract<br />

(represented by a transfer from store to brand) to maximize its expected category<br />

value. Given the contract, each potential brand makes a take-it-or-leave-it decision.<br />

With post-entry sales and transfer data available, we propose a structural model to<br />

incorporate post-entry outcome data into a static entry game <strong>of</strong> incomplete<br />

information where the outcome regression is selection-corrected by the inclusion <strong>of</strong><br />

entry game. This model is estimated using a direct constrained optimization approach<br />

which is robust to multiple equilibria and circumvents the heavy computation burden<br />

from traditional nested fixed-point algorithm. The model is applied to women’s<br />

clothing category, the largest category <strong>of</strong> department store, and capable <strong>of</strong> quantifying<br />

the magnitude <strong>of</strong> inter-brand spillovers. We find evidence <strong>of</strong> significant competition<br />

and complementarity (within and out <strong>of</strong> category) across different brand types and<br />

the selection bias from ignoring the entry decision. The estimation result helps to<br />

understand how inter-brand spillovers, brand selling cost and brand demand are<br />

interwined to yield observed category brand assortment and shed lights on retail<br />

category management.<br />

4 - An Empirical Model <strong>of</strong> Dynamic Re-entry, Advertising and Pricing<br />

Strategies in the Wake <strong>of</strong> Product<br />

Yi Zhao, Georgia State University, Suite 1300, 35 Broad Street,<br />

Atlanta, GA, 30303, United States <strong>of</strong> America, yizhao@gsu.edu,<br />

Ying Zhao, Yuxin Chen<br />

Product harm-crisis may become the worst nightmare for any firm at some point in<br />

time. It may affect both the demand side, such as consumer’s intrinsic preference and<br />

sensitivities to marketing mix, and the supply side such as costs and competition<br />

structures. Product-harm crisis always triggers a product recall, and in most cases the<br />

affected brand will return to store shelf after the crisis is solved. The timing <strong>of</strong> reentry<br />

can be a strategic decision for the firms. In this paper, we empirically study<br />

firms’ re-entry strategy after a major product-harm crisis, taking into account the<br />

demand side <strong>of</strong> market. Two other interactive strategies, pricing and advertising, are<br />

also modeled through Markov perfect equilibrium framework. The model is applied<br />

to product-harm crisis event that hits the peanut butter division <strong>of</strong> Kraft Food<br />

Australia in June 1996. Substantively we find that (1) the observed “large advertising<br />

expenditure” strategy for the unaffected brand before the affected brand re-enters the<br />

market is optimal, since a “large advertising expenditure” in this period plays an<br />

important role in postponing the time <strong>of</strong> re-entry for the affected brand; (2) the<br />

competition after the occurrence <strong>of</strong> the product-harm crisis becomes more intensive.<br />

The direct consequence <strong>of</strong> this is that both the affected and unaffected firms are<br />

forced to adopt “low margin” and “large advertising expenditure” (comparing with<br />

the pre-crisis advertising expenditure) strategies. As a result, the long-term<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>itabilities decrease, especially for the affected brand whose pr<strong>of</strong>itability decreases<br />

by 38%. Finally, the counterfactual experiments show that the increase in the effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> the state dependence is one <strong>of</strong> the major reasons for a more intensive competition<br />

after the product harm crisis.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!