22.07.2013 Views

Conceived in Liberty Volume 2 - Ludwig von Mises Institute

Conceived in Liberty Volume 2 - Ludwig von Mises Institute

Conceived in Liberty Volume 2 - Ludwig von Mises Institute

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>in</strong> Massachusetts <strong>in</strong> 1686. It is also a particularly <strong>in</strong>structive example of the<br />

k<strong>in</strong>ds of forces beh<strong>in</strong>d the <strong>in</strong>flationist proposals. The orig<strong>in</strong>ators of the<br />

scheme were emphatically not poor debtor-farmers. On the contrary, they were<br />

precisely the rul<strong>in</strong>g oligarchy of Massachusetts.<br />

The year 1686 saw Massachusetts ruled by Joseph Dudley and his associates<br />

<strong>in</strong> plunder. On assum<strong>in</strong>g office, Dudley and his Council appo<strong>in</strong>ted a committee<br />

of lead<strong>in</strong>g merchants and other citizens to study trade conditions. The<br />

committee, led by Capta<strong>in</strong> John Blackwell, reported with a proposal for a<br />

bank whose notes would be forced on the people as legal tender. The plan<br />

was to <strong>in</strong>clude all the lead<strong>in</strong>g oligarchs of the Dudley era <strong>in</strong> the directorship<br />

of the bank: Dudley himself, William Stoughton, Wait W<strong>in</strong>throp, Simon<br />

Lynde, Elisha Hutch<strong>in</strong>son, Elisha Cooke, and others. No notes were to be issued<br />

below twenty shill<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> denom<strong>in</strong>ation, to ensure that the bank would be<br />

largely limited to the wealthiest citizens. The bank was to have no specie capital<br />

whatever, though <strong>in</strong>dividual directors were to bear responsibility. The plan<br />

was abandoned with the arrival of Andros. The Glorious Revolution, <strong>in</strong> 1688,<br />

<strong>in</strong>spired new talk of the Blackwell bank, but aga<strong>in</strong> the proposal fell through.<br />

Paper money f<strong>in</strong>ally came to Massachusetts not <strong>in</strong> the form of a land bank's<br />

notes, but as the first issue of government paper money <strong>in</strong> the world, apart<br />

from medieval Ch<strong>in</strong>a.* Paper money can be issued either by government for<br />

direct spend<strong>in</strong>g, or by a bank, public or private, that lends out money to the<br />

public. While the former is cruder and more flagrant, it actually has less<br />

harmful repercussions on the economy. For, given the same amount of monetary<br />

issue, lend<strong>in</strong>g out the new money <strong>in</strong>flicts additional distortion on the<br />

loan market and <strong>in</strong>terest rates, which fact generates the familiar features of<br />

the boom-bust trade cycle.**<br />

The fateful plunge of Massachusetts <strong>in</strong>to paper money came through direct<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g rather than lend<strong>in</strong>g. Massachusetts had engaged <strong>in</strong> an expedition of<br />

plunder aga<strong>in</strong>st French Quebec, an expedition it hoped would more than pay<br />

for itself. But as luck would have it, the expedition failed ignom<strong>in</strong>iously, and<br />

Massachusetts was faced with the grave problem of pay<strong>in</strong>g the salaries of its<br />

soldiers who were on the edge of mut<strong>in</strong>y. The Massachusetts government<br />

tried to borrow from three to four thousand pounds from Boston merchants,<br />

but evidently its credit rat<strong>in</strong>g was far too low. Proceed<strong>in</strong>g upon the pr<strong>in</strong>ciple<br />

that if it could not raise money it must pr<strong>in</strong>t its own, Massachusetts decided<br />

<strong>in</strong> December 1690 to issue 7,000 pounds <strong>in</strong> paper notes. Now the government<br />

knew that it could not simply pr<strong>in</strong>t paper irredeemable <strong>in</strong> specie labeled<br />

*There is a s<strong>in</strong>gle exception: the Card Money of Quebec. In 1685 the govern<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>tendant of Quebec, Monsieur Meules, decided to augment his funds by divid<strong>in</strong>g some<br />

play<strong>in</strong>g cards <strong>in</strong>to quarters, mark<strong>in</strong>g them with various denom<strong>in</strong>ations, and then issu<strong>in</strong>g<br />

them to pay for wages and materials. Meules took the precaution of order<strong>in</strong>g the public<br />

to accept the cards (that is, legal tender); the cards were later redeemed with specie<br />

sent from France. Used repeatedly <strong>in</strong> Quebec, the money became play<strong>in</strong>g tickets rather<br />

than play<strong>in</strong>g cards.<br />

**For an explanation, see Murray N. Rothbard, America's Great Depression, 2d ed.<br />

(Los Angeles: Nash, 1972), pt. 1.<br />

130

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!