31.10.2012 Views

austin-murphy-the-triumph-of-evil

austin-murphy-the-triumph-of-evil

austin-murphy-the-triumph-of-evil

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

218 THE TRIUMPH OF EVIL<br />

(and <strong>of</strong>ten completely) at <strong>the</strong> whims <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> marketplace, and <strong>the</strong> 1990s<br />

have demonstrated that free markets can cause large fluctuations in cur­<br />

rency values which can have very serious effects on <strong>the</strong> international<br />

balance <strong>of</strong> payments, inflation, and economic output.<br />

A good example is provided by Yeltsin's capitalist Russia, which (at<br />

<strong>the</strong> suggestion <strong>of</strong> its primary USA economic advisor, Harvard Univer­<br />

sity Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Jeffrey Sachs) made its currency, <strong>the</strong> ruble (Rb), freely<br />

convertible in December <strong>of</strong> 1991 (Hays, 1991 ). Although <strong>the</strong> average<br />

purchasing power <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ruble in terms <strong>of</strong> what it could buy in real goods<br />

and services was approximately <strong>the</strong> same as <strong>the</strong> dollar before 1991 (and<br />

<strong>the</strong>refore approximated <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial government exchange rate between<br />

dollars and rubles that was about 1:1 at that time), Russia did not have<br />

<strong>the</strong> products, reputation, and distribution system to be competitive in<br />

international markets (Williamson, 1991 ). In addition, <strong>the</strong>re was enor­<br />

mous pent-up Russian demand for foreign products, including not only<br />

fo r electronics goods that had long been in short supply in Russia under<br />

communism but also for foreign brand-name versions <strong>of</strong> what was<br />

much more cheaply available in Russia such as blue jeans, cigarettes,<br />

and cola.<br />

This situation represented one <strong>of</strong> extreme inelasticity <strong>of</strong> demand rela­<br />

tive to price for Russian imports and exports (Caves, Frankel, and Jones,<br />

1996). In particular, Russians were willing to pay almost any price for<br />

foreign goods in 1991, and <strong>the</strong> demand for (or addiction to) foreign<br />

goods continues strong even many years later (Associated Press, 1998).<br />

On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, fo reign countries were unwilling to pay any price<br />

for Russian goods, which had not yet been adapted to sell in fo reign<br />

markets, which had a poor reputation (from Cold War propaganda) if<br />

<strong>the</strong>y were known about at all, and which were not even being interna­<br />

tionally distributed yet on any large scale (with <strong>the</strong> marketing necessary<br />

to "sell" and distribute products in capitalism being a very costly and<br />

time-consuming process).<br />

As a result, when <strong>the</strong> ruble went from being almost fu lly inconvert­<br />

ible (in terms <strong>of</strong> severe restrictions on any currency trading) to sud­<br />

denly being fu lly convertible in December <strong>of</strong> 1991, <strong>the</strong>re was an enor­<br />

mous demand fo r fo reign currencies like dollars and almost no demand<br />

for rubles. Not surprisingly, <strong>the</strong> currency immediately fe ll from about<br />

Rb l/$ to about Rb 100/$.<br />

CHAPTER 6 219<br />

Such an enormous devaluation had an effect similar to making <strong>the</strong><br />

currency worthless, which would reduce hard currency exports to $0<br />

if prices in <strong>the</strong> domestic currency remained <strong>the</strong> same. For instance, a<br />

vodka exporter selling bottles at Rb5/bottle would have <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong><br />

dollars earned per bottle fall from $5 to $.05 when <strong>the</strong> exchange rate<br />

changed from Rbl/$ to RblOO/$. At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> dollar retail<br />

price in an export market like <strong>the</strong> US might only fall by about a third<br />

because transportation costs, tariffs, li.q uor taxes, and distribution costs<br />

such as dealer mark-ups typically make up more than 2/3 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> final<br />

retail price, and <strong>the</strong>se costs may be largely independent <strong>of</strong> exchange<br />

rates-as is also typical for many o<strong>the</strong>r products (such as textiles) pro­<br />

duced in less developed countries, where even non-transportation dis­<br />

tribution costs (i.e., rent and capital costs incorporated into wholesale<br />

and retail mark-ups) easily make up over 2/3 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> retail value (Chos­<br />

sudovsky, 1997). Even !f<strong>the</strong> 33% drop in <strong>the</strong> retail price could lead to<br />

a doubling <strong>of</strong> sales to 2 million bottles from 1 million, <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong><br />

export revenue would fall from $5 million to 2,000,000x$.05=$ 1 00,000.<br />

ln. <strong>the</strong> meantime, "needed" technology and Western brand-name imports<br />

ought only be halved despite 9900% higher Rb costs (caused by <strong>the</strong><br />

99% devaluation), resulting in a 4900% increase in Rb imports that can<br />

not be paid for with a 100% increase in Rb exports. In this situation,<br />

<strong>the</strong>re was virtually no exchange rate that would balance <strong>the</strong> payments<br />

for trade (or <strong>the</strong> international current account). Only investors seeking<br />

to<br />

. buy up Russian real estate and fixed assets at some extremely low<br />

pnces (like 11100 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> prior cost) could bring <strong>the</strong> supply and demand<br />

for rubles into <strong>the</strong> equilibrium at 100 rubles per dollar.<br />

However, such a situation could not and did not last long. Exporters<br />

prefer not to maximize revenue in a worthless currency, and so <strong>the</strong>y<br />

naturally increase <strong>the</strong>ir domestic currency prices in such a predicament<br />

M � ps using collusion), unless <strong>the</strong>re is both perfect competition and<br />

�cJent capacity to meet <strong>the</strong> higher unit demand. With importers also<br />

vmg to raise ruble prices to pay <strong>the</strong> same dollar price but with far<br />

�ore � bles (and with those competing with importers doing likewise),<br />

; :on rising from 5.4% in 1990 to about 1 000/o by <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1991 and<br />

� � t trnmediate hyperinflation in Russia was <strong>the</strong> natural result, with<br />

1�1 ut 13� % in 1992 (IMF, 1993). At <strong>the</strong> time <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> devaluation in<br />

'<strong>the</strong> chatrman <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Russian central bank (who disagreed strongly

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!