31.10.2012 Views

austin-murphy-the-triumph-of-evil

austin-murphy-the-triumph-of-evil

austin-murphy-the-triumph-of-evil

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

296 THE TRIUMPH OF EVIL<br />

in <strong>the</strong> real output computations, since doing so results in an overstating <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

growth for capitalist countries that increase <strong>the</strong>ir spending on selling, repackaging, and<br />

unnecessarily complicating a basic service that communist systems provide so much<br />

more effectively and less confusingly, i.e., with less risk and analysis time lost to <strong>the</strong><br />

individual). rt should also be mentioned that <strong>of</strong>ficial output accounts in all countries<br />

systematically leave out some economic activity, such as unreported output by tax dodg­<br />

ers and o<strong>the</strong>r law evaders (some <strong>of</strong> whom provide useful products or services). Also,<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficial accounts don't take into consideration most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> output produced by individuals<br />

and families for <strong>the</strong>mselves (this latter unreported output was probably much higher<br />

fo r East Germany, since shortages <strong>the</strong>re motivated individuals to do many things on<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir own instead <strong>of</strong> purchasing <strong>the</strong>m, as commercially sold consumer services made up<br />

a relatively small portion <strong>of</strong> National Income because <strong>the</strong> dominating state businesses<br />

put far more resources into production).<br />

6. Some, such as Merkel and Wahl ( 1991) and Schwarzer ( 1999), have suggested that<br />

<strong>the</strong> actual prices paid for all goods should be adjusted for a price ratio determined by<br />

some very narrowly-traded products when estimating <strong>the</strong> actual inflation rate needed<br />

to deflate nominal output to compute real output growth. However, even an anticom·<br />

munist propagandist like Ritschl ( 1996) has called such an arbitrary, biased, and ina ­ �<br />

curate practice "obviously questionable," especially since <strong>the</strong> chosen traded goods dtd<br />

not include big essentials like housing, which East Gennany heavily subsidized. Th<br />

.<br />

e<br />

use <strong>of</strong> such exchange rates to evaluate relative income, living standards, and output ts<br />

about as ridiculous as using <strong>the</strong> black market exchange rate, which had only a very<br />

narrow use and varied widely, being as high as 20 East German Marks per West G<br />

.<br />

erman<br />

Mark on <strong>the</strong> day after <strong>the</strong> Wall opened up in November 1989 (Nawrocki, 1987), tmply·<br />

ing an absurd ratio <strong>of</strong> per capita income in <strong>the</strong> two countries <strong>of</strong> about 40 to I on that<br />

day.<br />

7. This exchange rate is consistent with <strong>the</strong> cross-rate between East German Marks<br />

and West German Marks implied by Stolper's ( 1960) estimated valuation ratio <strong>of</strong> 1 748<br />

:<br />

West German Marks in 1950 per 1936 Reichsmark and his citation <strong>of</strong> a 1936 Retchs·<br />

mark having <strong>the</strong> same purchasing power as 4. 186 East German Marks in 1950. These<br />

data imply that <strong>the</strong> East Gennan Mark was worth 1.748/4. 186=0.42 West Ge��<br />

Marks at that time. Although a drastic reduction in reparations payments permtlt<br />

East German consumer prices to be lowered significantly after 1953 (Weber, 1988),<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial economic statistics (reported by each country) indicate negligible aggreg�te<br />

inflation (on all output) in both East and West Germany in <strong>the</strong> 1950s, thus implytng<br />

approximately <strong>the</strong> same relative purchasing power (0.42 West German Marks per East<br />

German Mark) in 1961 as in 1950. Despite <strong>the</strong> fact that both East and West Germany<br />

initially had <strong>the</strong> same Mark currency between 1945 and 1947, <strong>the</strong> USSR (in an attempt<br />

to circumvent <strong>the</strong> USA's refusal to allow West Germany to pay its share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> �tions)<br />

had caused East Germany to print excessive amounts <strong>of</strong> money to pay reparattons<br />

(Schwarzer, 1 999), and <strong>the</strong> USA reacted by causing West Germany to form a separate<br />

currency that was not subject to <strong>the</strong> reparations-induced inflation <strong>of</strong> East Germany. As<br />

a result, in 1948, after <strong>the</strong> establishment <strong>of</strong> separate currencies for East and West Ger·<br />

many, <strong>the</strong>re were over twice as many East German Marks per East German resident �<br />

.<br />

West German Marks per West German resident, and, despite a continued I : I <strong>of</strong>ficta<br />

k<br />

exchange rate (which was only honored for some specified currency trades), <strong>the</strong> blac<br />

NoTES 297<br />

Olllket exchange rate was 0.27 West German Marks per East German Mark late in 1948<br />

and fell below 0.2 West German Marks in <strong>the</strong> early 1950s (Schwarzer, 1 999).<br />

8. Many prior studies <strong>of</strong> relative income may have overestimated relative East German<br />

income at various points in <strong>the</strong> past, at least partially because <strong>of</strong> an overestimate <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> East German Mark in <strong>the</strong> aggregate (Gregory and Leptin, 1977). Previous<br />

research has shown <strong>the</strong> relative consumption purchasing power <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> East German<br />

Muk to have generally exhibited a rising trend over time that is consistent with <strong>the</strong><br />

higher inflation in West Germany, with <strong>the</strong> currency having been estimated to be worth<br />

0.88 West German Marks in 1973 (Gregory and Leptin, 1977), 1.06 West German<br />

Marks in 1980 (Collier, 1985), and values averaging about 1.13 West German Marts<br />

in tbe early 1980s (DIW, 1984). However, <strong>the</strong>se values may not fully incorporate quality<br />

differences, and <strong>the</strong>y definitely do not include producer prices, which were much<br />

higher in East Germany because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> East German government's taxes on industry to<br />

finance subsidization <strong>of</strong> consumer prices (Schwarzer, 1999). As a result, such past figeovcrstate<br />

<strong>the</strong> true aggregate economic purchasing power <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> East German Mark<br />

on those dates and <strong>the</strong>refore also result in overestimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> comparative income <strong>of</strong><br />

East Getmany at those times. East Germany itself overestimated its relative per capita<br />

income in 1960 to be only 30% below that <strong>of</strong> West Germany, but this estimate was<br />

likely based on its clearly overvalued <strong>of</strong>ficial I: I exchange rate (that it felt necessary to<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficially support and that at sci enabled it to make an apparently futile attempt to keep<br />

its wortc force in <strong>the</strong> country with optimistic statements about relative living standards),<br />

wbcRas actual East German income per capita was probably about 40% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> West<br />

German level at that time (Merkel and Wahl, 1991 ).<br />

9. The relative pricing <strong>of</strong> goods and services in international trade may also have led<br />

�economic advantages for West Germany. For instance, because <strong>of</strong> superior market­<br />

llllllld protectionist trade policies in West Germany, <strong>the</strong> West German Mark was <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

�ued in <strong>the</strong> currency markets relative to its purchasing power, and this overvalu-<br />

111011<br />

provided West Germany with terms <strong>of</strong> trade advantages with <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world<br />

(Murphy, t992a). On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand. East German terms <strong>of</strong> trade suffered not only from<br />

lrlde barriers erected by capitalist countries against communist countries (Melzer and<br />

&ahnke. 1986) but also from <strong>the</strong> negative worldwide propaganda leveled against p�­<br />

� from communist countries (Szczesny, 2000a) that was both political an� econo � 1c<br />

111 content and purpose. East German terms <strong>of</strong> trade with <strong>the</strong>ir larger Russtan tradmg<br />

l'ltneq, which were determined by negotiation, did not produce any <strong>of</strong>fsetting advan­<br />

� for East Germany, as slow adjustments to world market prices for many commod­<br />

Ity trades provided East European countries with temporary advantages and disadvan­<br />

� began to charge prices for oil that more reflected world market prices (Ritschl,<br />

llacs that tended to cancel out (Mendershausen, 1960), until <strong>the</strong> late 1980s when <strong>the</strong><br />

996).<br />

� to be hi . gher under communism than under capitalism (Die� 1976), <strong>the</strong> find . ing <strong>of</strong><br />

.10 · Whereas o<strong>the</strong>r studies have also shown economic growth in less developed coun­<br />

· �<br />

15 especially important because it compares two relatiVely advan�, mdus­<br />

��� economies. This comparison <strong>of</strong> real economic growth measures rel � ttve effi­<br />

�.•n &ggregate terms <strong>of</strong> mobilizing and managing resources. Comparative return<br />

:• figures are not separately analyzed in this �per �use marginal re�s t�<br />

are <strong>of</strong>ten more a function <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> percent <strong>of</strong> nattonal mcome allocated to mvest

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!