31.10.2012 Views

austin-murphy-the-triumph-of-evil

austin-murphy-the-triumph-of-evil

austin-murphy-the-triumph-of-evil

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

294 THE TRIUMPH OF EVIL<br />

against <strong>the</strong> presidential "party slates" in <strong>the</strong> USA. In two <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> three attempts I required<br />

<strong>the</strong> assistance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> voter registration <strong>of</strong>ficials, who largely ridiculed my vote publicly,<br />

and in <strong>the</strong> third attempt, I doubt my vote was properly counted. My conversations with<br />

East German dissidents who attempted to vote against <strong>the</strong> party slate before <strong>the</strong> revolu­<br />

tion indicate a similar system in East Germany, where simply marking a ballot with an<br />

"X" represented a vote for <strong>the</strong> candidate list, and where use <strong>of</strong> a closed voting booth to<br />

register a secret ballot was ridiculed by those in <strong>the</strong> queue who were anxious to return<br />

to <strong>the</strong>ir own business. In addition, it should also be mentioned that claims <strong>of</strong> outright<br />

fraudulent voter counts have also been alleged in <strong>the</strong> USA in recent times (Collier and<br />

Collier, 1992).<br />

II. Opp and Gem ( 1993) have estimated 124,500 to 166,000 participants in <strong>the</strong> Octo<br />

ber 9, 1989 demonstration in Leipzig. In survey interviews conducted after unifica­<br />

tion, <strong>the</strong>se investigators stated that <strong>the</strong> demonstration seemed to be fa irly spontaneous<br />

without any apparent leaders, although it is interesting to note that <strong>the</strong>ir research did<br />

not allude at all to <strong>the</strong> public announcements played on <strong>the</strong> radio and on loudspeakers<br />

essentially condoning <strong>the</strong> demonstration (implying that ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> two Western researchers<br />

conducted very superficial interviews, or <strong>the</strong>y have a political agenda that motivated<br />

<strong>the</strong>m not to report such seemingly important facts).<br />

12. It is also instructive to see that Western-oriented "free" market advocates, who<br />

applauded <strong>the</strong> Soviet Union's movement to "democracy" under Yeltsin in 1991, pro<br />

vided no opposition to Ye ltsin's appointment <strong>of</strong> his former head <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> secret police,<br />

Vladimir Putin (who had been a KGB <strong>of</strong>ficer in <strong>the</strong> 1980s), as his successor in 1999<br />

(Cullison, 2000a), although <strong>the</strong>y did formally protest Putin's bringing people with l�ftwing<br />

opinions into <strong>the</strong> government (Chazan, 2000a). These "freedom" advocates (hke<br />

<strong>the</strong> Ukrainians who collaborated with Hitler and who worked with <strong>the</strong> CIA to enact a<br />

violent return <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Nazi "freedom" to exploit and kill) <strong>the</strong>reby confirmed that �heir<br />

only real concern was about <strong>the</strong> "freedom" <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> marketplace (which, as explamed<br />

throughout this book, restricts people's freedom and creates an enormous amount <strong>of</strong><br />

repression and suffering in people's lives).<br />

CHAPTER 4<br />

1. Many <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se problems are magnified in West Germany because <strong>the</strong> financial<br />

markets are less liquid than more developed capitalist markets such as in <strong>the</strong> USA.<br />

However, for private firms in East Germany that operated outside <strong>of</strong> state control, <strong>the</strong><br />

cost <strong>of</strong> capital was even higher than in West Germany because <strong>of</strong> heavy income taxa·<br />

tion (90% for firms that do not supply services or essentials) and legal restrictions 00<br />

<strong>the</strong> maximum number <strong>of</strong> employees (10), as explained in Der Tagesspiegel (1989a,<br />

1989d).<br />

2. This estimated purchasing power value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> East German Mark is also consistent<br />

with <strong>the</strong> consumer price inftation figures reported by <strong>the</strong> West German govemme�t,<br />

which showed eastern German inftation to be 2% lower than in western GermanY Jn<br />

1990 but 12% higher in 1991 (Statistisches Bundesamt, 1992). These numbers, when<br />

combined with <strong>the</strong> 16% higher inftation in eastern Germany after 1991, imply that <strong>the</strong><br />

consumer purchasing power <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> East German Mark was equal to about 1 .28 West<br />

German Marks. However, given that such purchasing power might apply to no more<br />

than 80% <strong>of</strong> East German National Income, and given <strong>the</strong> fact that East German pro-<br />

NarES 295<br />

ducer prices fe ll by 500/o in 1990 to a distressed level well below <strong>the</strong>ir true value (van<br />

Ark, 1995), <strong>the</strong> weighted-average aggregate inftation in eastern Germany was likely<br />

closer to 15% higher than in western Germany after 1989, implying <strong>the</strong> 1989 exchange<br />

me <strong>of</strong> 1.15 West Germany Marks per East German Mark. This estimate may actually<br />

be too low, as one West German study indicated that, instead <strong>of</strong> insignificantly changing<br />

during <strong>the</strong> time around <strong>the</strong> transformation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> East German Mark into <strong>the</strong> West<br />

Gennan Mark, consumer prices in East Germany actually rose by over 25% between<br />

January and July 1990 (Wei fens, 1992). Such a figure (combined with <strong>the</strong> subsequently<br />

higher inflation in eastern Germany as its prices continued to rise to western German<br />

levels over time), might imply <strong>the</strong> consumer purchasing power <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> East German<br />

M� was equal to that <strong>of</strong> 1.60 West German Marks (although <strong>the</strong> latter estimate may<br />

nol fully adjust for quality differentials).<br />

3. Data inconsistencies on relative living standards (Shrnelev and Popov, 1989)<br />

caused by <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial or black market exchange rates can greatly distort real<br />

income comparisons because <strong>the</strong>y are extremely poor indicators <strong>of</strong> true purchasing<br />

power, as shown by Sheikh (1976), Schmitt (1980) and Daniel (1986). Such distortions<br />

are avoided here because it is possible to use estimated purchasing power parity<br />

exchange rates that are verified by <strong>the</strong> much higher prices that appeared in East Germany<br />

when <strong>the</strong>y were denominated in West German Marks compared to East German<br />

Marks earlier (Neues Deutschland, 1991). While Shmelev and Popov (1989) have<br />

hypo<strong>the</strong>sized that <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> shortages and o<strong>the</strong>r problems may make figures from<br />

10111C Eastern European countries suspect, Collier ( 1985) has found <strong>the</strong> East German<br />

figures to be fa irly reliable, even after adjusting for shortages. In addition, although<br />

�Art (1995) estimated East German industrial productivity to be only 300/o <strong>of</strong> that<br />

11 West Germany, his results are severely biased by an industrial purchasing power<br />

comparison that failed to adjust for East Germany's heavy levies on industry to finance<br />

COIIIUmption good subsidies.<br />

4. Note that <strong>the</strong> 27% ratio <strong>of</strong> investment to National Income is measured gross <strong>of</strong><br />

�iation, i.e., it includes capital investment undertaken to replace depreciated assets.<br />

Investment net <strong>of</strong> depreciation averaged only slightly over 20% <strong>of</strong> National Income in<br />

East Germany.<br />

S. While individual national account figures in all countries are subject to large error<br />

IMorsenstem, 1963), no significant overstatement <strong>of</strong> output has ever been found for<br />

lbe_East German accounts, which Schwarzer (1999) has cited as being as accurate as<br />

lltlonal accounts for Western countries. Unbiased errors in national income should<br />

'-�ely cancel out over <strong>the</strong> long time interval examined. Although Ritschl ( 1996) has<br />

� 1 study indicating that East German output figures may have underweighted some<br />

:: JI'Oduction (compared to West German weighting) and that East Gennan �<br />

��German growth would still indicate it to be significantly higher than in West<br />

·<br />

&rowth may have <strong>the</strong>refore been overstated by I% annually, such a reductton<br />

� .. ....y. It should also be noted that virtually all <strong>of</strong> this alleged neglected "output"<br />

� effect is in <strong>the</strong> area <strong>of</strong> financial services, which <strong>the</strong> East German government<br />

�ly provided via a very simple cheap and efficient system <strong>of</strong> savings, pen­<br />

� llld insurance (Merkel and Wahl t991) a� which can correctly be considered to<br />

011: . COlt f<br />

•<br />

0 real output (i.e., a cost <strong>of</strong> allocating funds to future consumption<br />

' '<br />

0 and needs)<br />

OJIJioled to being an output itself (and <strong>the</strong>oretically should <strong>the</strong>refore not be mcluded<br />

.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!