31.08.2013 Views

A systematic review and economic model of the effectiveness and ...

A systematic review and economic model of the effectiveness and ...

A systematic review and economic model of the effectiveness and ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

112<br />

Economic <strong>model</strong><br />

TABLE 92 Alternative utility values used in sensitivity analysis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>economic</strong> <strong>model</strong><br />

Health state Utility value (SE)<br />

Responder to ATX, no side-effects 0.959 (0.077)<br />

Responder to IR-MPH, no side-effects 0.913 (0.128)<br />

Responder to ER-MPH, no side-effects 0.930 (0.107)<br />

Non-responder, no medication 0.880 (0.133)<br />

SE, st<strong>and</strong>ard error.<br />

Sensitivity to estimated utility values<br />

The base case analysis employs estimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

utility associated with response to treatment <strong>and</strong><br />

non-response to treatment that are independent <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> treatment received. A responder to ATX<br />

<strong>the</strong>refore receives <strong>the</strong> same utility value as a<br />

responder to MPH or DEX. The submission by Eli<br />

Lilly utilised a different set <strong>of</strong> utility estimates<br />

derived using SG methodology. These estimates<br />

valued response (<strong>and</strong> non-response) to treatment<br />

dependent on <strong>the</strong> medication received. Hence<br />

separate values were available for response (<strong>and</strong><br />

non-response) to ATX, IR-MPH <strong>and</strong> ER-MPH,<br />

also separated by <strong>the</strong> presence or absence <strong>of</strong><br />

treatment side-effects. The <strong>review</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> company<br />

submissions highlighted some concerns about <strong>the</strong><br />

validity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se estimates, particularly <strong>the</strong> fact<br />

that <strong>the</strong> utility <strong>of</strong> a non-responder without sideeffects<br />

differs between treatments. For example,<br />

<strong>the</strong> utility associated with non-response to ATX,<br />

without side-effects, is estimated to be 0.902,<br />

which compares with an estimated utility <strong>of</strong> 0.880<br />

associated with non-response <strong>and</strong> no medication.<br />

A difference in utility <strong>of</strong> 0.022 is relatively large in<br />

this population, particularly between health states<br />

with identical characteristics.<br />

A sensitivity analysis was conducted using <strong>the</strong>se<br />

alternative estimates <strong>of</strong> utility. The reason for <strong>the</strong><br />

differences in utility <strong>of</strong> non-response by treatment<br />

(including no treatment) is unclear, so <strong>the</strong><br />

sensitivity analysis uses <strong>the</strong> utility <strong>of</strong> non-response<br />

associated with no medication. Our <strong>model</strong> does<br />

not separate responders into those with sideeffects<br />

<strong>and</strong> those without, so we conducted <strong>the</strong><br />

sensitivity analysis including <strong>the</strong> utility <strong>of</strong> response<br />

without side-effects. Table 92 shows <strong>the</strong> utility<br />

values used in this sensitivity analysis.<br />

The health state descriptions used to obtain <strong>the</strong>se<br />

valuations are shown in Appendix 10. These<br />

vignettes were designed to maximise <strong>the</strong><br />

differences between treatments. The results <strong>of</strong> this<br />

sensitivity analysis rely on <strong>the</strong> validity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se<br />

health state descriptions. No estimate was<br />

available for DEX, so <strong>the</strong> utility associated with IR-<br />

MPH was applied to patients responding to DEX,<br />

in accordance with <strong>the</strong> assumption made in <strong>the</strong><br />

submission by Eli Lilly.<br />

The results <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> sensitivity analysis are shown in<br />

Table 93. Strategy 13 remained <strong>the</strong> cheapest<br />

strategy, but it no longer dominated <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

strategies. By calculating <strong>the</strong> ICERs, according to<br />

<strong>the</strong> rules <strong>of</strong> dominance <strong>and</strong> extended dominance<br />

(p. 95), we see that strategies 5, 10, 11 <strong>and</strong> 16 are<br />

not ruled out by dominance or extended<br />

dominance. Strategies 5, 10 <strong>and</strong> 11 all feature<br />

ATX as first-line <strong>the</strong>rapy. This is unsurprising<br />

given that a response to ATX is associated with a<br />

utility gain <strong>of</strong> 0.046 over a response to IR-MPH<br />

(<strong>and</strong> DEX). Response to ATX is associated with a<br />

utility gain <strong>of</strong> 0.079 compared with non-response<br />

with no treatment, whereas response to IR-MPH<br />

entails a gain <strong>of</strong> only 0.033 over non-response<br />

with no treatment. For comparison, in <strong>the</strong> base<br />

case analysis, response is associated with a utility<br />

gain <strong>of</strong> 0.064 compared with non-response.<br />

Figure 24 shows <strong>the</strong> cost-<strong>effectiveness</strong> acceptability<br />

frontier for <strong>the</strong> optimal strategies in this sensitivity<br />

analysis. If society were willing to pay £30,000 per<br />

additional QALY, strategy 11 is <strong>the</strong> optimal<br />

strategy with a 3% probability <strong>of</strong> being <strong>the</strong> optimal<br />

strategy.<br />

The discontinuities in <strong>the</strong> frontier in Figure 24<br />

illustrate that <strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> incremental net<br />

benefit is skewed. Strategies 13 <strong>and</strong> 6 have a<br />

higher probability <strong>of</strong> being cost-effective than<br />

strategies 5, 10, 11 <strong>and</strong> 16 for values <strong>of</strong> willingness<br />

to pay per QALY >£11,000, but <strong>the</strong>y do not have<br />

<strong>the</strong> highest expected net benefit.<br />

Co-morbid conditions<br />

The base case analysis does not include <strong>the</strong><br />

additional costs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> common co-morbid<br />

conditions <strong>of</strong> CD <strong>and</strong> ODD. Estimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

additional cost <strong>of</strong> common co-morbid conditions<br />

were available from <strong>the</strong> same source that provided

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!