11.10.2015 Views

DELIVERING THE CIRCULAR ECONOMY A TOOLKIT FOR POLICYMAKERS

20150924_Policymakers-Toolkit_Active-links

20150924_Policymakers-Toolkit_Active-links

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

80 • <strong>DELIVERING</strong> <strong>THE</strong> <strong>CIRCULAR</strong> <strong>ECONOMY</strong> – A <strong>TOOLKIT</strong> <strong>FOR</strong> <strong>POLICYMAKERS</strong><br />

Setting clear direction<br />

As set out in Section 2.1.2, adopting a national ambition level using appropriate targets<br />

– based on, for example, the three circular economy principles, as described in Section<br />

2.1.2 – might send a powerful signal to businesses and investors. Setting out a clear<br />

economy-wide strategy on circular economy and resource productivity might do so as<br />

well, and governments have already begun to do so. Existing national circular economy<br />

or resource productivity strategies include China’s Circular Economy Promotion Law,<br />

Japan’s Law for the Promotion of Effective Utilization of Resources, the UK Resource<br />

Security Action Plan: Making the most of valuable materials, Germany’s Resource<br />

Efficiency Programme (ProgRess) – see Table 2 for details – and the Netherlands’<br />

Waste to Resource strategy. In Scotland’s Economic Strategy 2015 remanufacturing was<br />

identified as a strategically important innovation sector.<br />

Realigned incentives<br />

While many circular economy opportunities already have a sound underlying<br />

profitability, realigning incentives from resources to labour could potentially unlock<br />

further opportunities. Such shifts are sensitive and need to be seen in the light of<br />

issues such as international competitiveness, stability of tax revenues, administrative<br />

complexity and potential distributional effects. They are, however, an option to explore<br />

since there is some evidence that they could bring economic and societal benefits (see<br />

below).<br />

A number of international organisations, such as the European Commission, the OECD,<br />

the IMF, and the International Labour Organization, have suggested shifting taxation<br />

from labour to resources. 97 They propose that such a shift could increase incentives to<br />

minimise waste, maximise resource productivity and increase the feasibility of more<br />

labour-intensive circular business practices. Ex’Tax has done detailed analysis on the<br />

practicalities and implications of such a shift. Its report presents a case study that<br />

finds that a (mid- to long-term) tax shift could shift more than EUR 30 billion in tax<br />

revenues from labour to resources and consumption in the Netherlands alone and, if<br />

internationally coordinated, could potentially create hundreds of thousands of jobs 98 . As,<br />

in Europe, 6% of total tax revenues originate from environmental taxes (including taxes<br />

levied on energy, transport, pollution and resource extraction), and 51% from labour<br />

taxes and social contributions 99 , there might be – at least in theory – significant scope to<br />

shift taxes from labour to resources.<br />

The IEA, the World Bank and the IMF, among others, have studied fossil fuel subsidies<br />

and their economic and environmental implications 100 . An IMF working paper from May<br />

2015 101 estimates global fossil fuel subsidies in 2014 to have been USD 5.6 trillion (7% of<br />

global GDP). The report states that “[eliminating] post-tax subsidies in 2015 could raise<br />

government revenue by USD 2.9 trillion (3.6% of global GDP), cut global CO 2<br />

emissions<br />

by more than 20%, and cut premature air pollution deaths by more than half. After<br />

allowing for the higher energy costs faced by consumers, this action would raise global<br />

economic welfare by USD 1.8 trillion (2.2% of global GDP).”<br />

There are however significant concerns about shifting taxation, most notably about<br />

distributional effects, the volatility of the tax base after the transformation and the<br />

potential for weakened competitiveness of primary materials and heavy industry.<br />

Policymakers that are considering tax shifts would need to investigate avenues<br />

to alleviate such concerns, which might include but are not limited to: mitigating<br />

distributional effects by increasing personal tax-free allowances and providing<br />

compensatory subsidies to those on fixed incomes and/or outside the labour market. To<br />

implement such a shift, policymakers would have to find widespread consensus on what<br />

97 Stahel, W. R., Palgrave Macmillan, The Performance Economy (2006).<br />

98 The Ex’Tax Project, in cooperation with Deloitte, EY, KPMG Meijburg and PwC, New Era. New Plan: Fiscal<br />

reforms for an inclusive, circular economy (2014).<br />

99 Eurostat, Taxation Trends in the EU (2014).<br />

100 See for example www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2012/05/09/real-costs-fossil-fuel-subsidies and www.<br />

worldenergyoutlook.org/resources/energysubsidies/<br />

101 IMF Working Paper, How Large Are Global Energy Subsidies (2014).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!