27.03.2013 Views

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

| 30 |<br />

International debt relief initiatives and <strong>the</strong>ir effects<br />

debt, i.e. <strong>the</strong> present value <strong>of</strong> all future debt service payments that would effectively have<br />

been paid by <strong>the</strong> deb<strong>to</strong>r (in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> debt relief), <strong>with</strong> present value again measured<br />

using <strong>the</strong> same discount rate. An EV lower than <strong>the</strong> PV in principle leads <strong>to</strong> a reduction in<br />

book value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> debt in <strong>the</strong> balances <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> credi<strong>to</strong>r, and <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> extent that <strong>the</strong>re is an<br />

active secondary market for that debt, is reflected in market values below par (and market<br />

prices below 100%).<br />

The same goes for valuing and assessing debt (s<strong>to</strong>ck) relief. The nominal debt s<strong>to</strong>ck relief<br />

will in general not be a good indica<strong>to</strong>r <strong>of</strong> say, <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> net additional resources that<br />

are now available in <strong>the</strong> recipient country government budget (net fiscal space). First <strong>of</strong> all,<br />

budgetary gains from debt relief only gradually materialise over time, at <strong>the</strong> pace <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

contractual debt service payments cancelled (<strong>the</strong> exact timing depending on <strong>the</strong> specific<br />

repayment terms and schedule). Again, <strong>the</strong> PV <strong>of</strong> all future contractual debt service<br />

payments that are forgiven (discounted at some market interest rate, or more appropriately,<br />

<strong>the</strong> interest rate at which <strong>the</strong> deb<strong>to</strong>r country can raise <strong>the</strong>se funds on its domestic market) is<br />

arguably a more correct measure since it takes in<strong>to</strong> account <strong>the</strong> time value <strong>of</strong> money. And<br />

even a considerable debt relief in PV terms, can only have modest debt service relief<br />

consequences in <strong>the</strong> short term, when all <strong>the</strong> debt service payments were due in <strong>the</strong> more<br />

distant future.<br />

Secondly, <strong>the</strong> PV <strong>of</strong> debt relief, and <strong>the</strong> short term debt service relief involved, again<br />

implicitly assumes that debt would have been fully serviced in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> any debt<br />

relief operation, which is also overly optimistic, especially for countries experiencing debt<br />

service problems. If not all debt would have been serviced, <strong>the</strong> eventual resource effect <strong>of</strong><br />

debt reduction is (at least partly) virtual, referring <strong>to</strong> an ‘accounting clean-up <strong>of</strong> his<strong>to</strong>rical<br />

and future arrears accumulation’ (Cassimon and Vaessen 2007, 14). Only <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> debt<br />

service that would have been actually paid up <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> credi<strong>to</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> debt relief<br />

generates real fiscal space, which is referred <strong>to</strong> as <strong>the</strong> economic value <strong>of</strong> debt (service)<br />

relief.<br />

Third, debt relief operations may lead <strong>to</strong> a crowding out <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, potentially more effective<br />

aid interventions. All <strong>to</strong>o <strong>of</strong>ten it is assumed that debt swaps take place in addition <strong>to</strong> all<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r forms <strong>of</strong> donor support, especially when swaps concern countries and debt titles<br />

falling outside <strong>the</strong> HIPC framework. However, full donor additionality cannot<br />

au<strong>to</strong>matically be taken as <strong>the</strong> default situation; substitution <strong>of</strong> donor effort can be at play.<br />

As such, one can not au<strong>to</strong>matically assume that debt relief leads <strong>to</strong> increased net fiscal<br />

space.<br />

Finally, from a donor perspective, even increased net fiscal space in <strong>the</strong> budget does not<br />

au<strong>to</strong>matically lead <strong>to</strong> increased development expenditure by <strong>the</strong> recipient public sec<strong>to</strong>r.<br />

One could imagine a situation wherein debt relief savings simply substitute for <strong>the</strong><br />

recipient country’s own development expenses; this so-called ‘fungibility’ <strong>of</strong> funds is<br />

inherent <strong>to</strong> most donor support, not only <strong>to</strong> debt relief. Donors try <strong>to</strong> manage this by <strong>the</strong><br />

appropriate use <strong>of</strong> conditionalities.<br />

<strong>Coming</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>Terms</strong> <strong>with</strong> <strong>Reality</strong><br />

2.1.2 A taxonomy <strong>of</strong> sovereign debt claims<br />

Table 2.1 fur<strong>the</strong>r distinguishes between <strong>the</strong> main types <strong>of</strong> (external) sovereign debt,<br />

according <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> type <strong>of</strong> credi<strong>to</strong>r. Credi<strong>to</strong>rs can be ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>of</strong>ficial or private (commercial).<br />

The <strong>of</strong>ficial credi<strong>to</strong>rs are ei<strong>the</strong>r bilateral credi<strong>to</strong>rs (o<strong>the</strong>r countries) or multilateral<br />

organisations (IMF, World bank, regional development banks, etc.). Multilateral<br />

organisations provide both concessional, as well as non-concessional loans. Also for<br />

bilateral credi<strong>to</strong>rs, two basic types <strong>of</strong> claims exist. First <strong>of</strong> all, bilateral credi<strong>to</strong>rs typically<br />

provide loans at concessional terms. For bilateral donors/credi<strong>to</strong>rs that report <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> DAC,<br />

<strong>the</strong>se loans are considered aid, and can be accounted for as Official Development<br />

Assistance (see section 2.4); <strong>the</strong>se are so-called ODA loans. Ano<strong>the</strong>r major part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

bilateral claims constitutes <strong>of</strong> non-concessional claims, which are not accounted for as aid<br />

(and ODA); <strong>the</strong>y are generally referred <strong>to</strong> as OOF (O<strong>the</strong>r Official Claims). Almost<br />

exclusively, <strong>the</strong>y relate <strong>to</strong> export credits, insured by (semi-) public Export Credit Agencies,<br />

and, because <strong>of</strong> payments default <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> original credi<strong>to</strong>r, now in <strong>the</strong> hands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ECA, and<br />

being acknowledged by <strong>the</strong> debt country as a sovereign claim 6 .<br />

This taxonomy will also be used from section 2.2 onwards when we discuss <strong>the</strong> different<br />

debt relief initiatives and interventions.<br />

2.2 Description on international debt relief initiatives<br />

2.2.1 A brief chronological description <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> major debt relief initiatives<br />

The his<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> debt relief goes back a long way, at least <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1950s, involving a whole<br />

range <strong>of</strong> bilateral, multilateral and commercial credi<strong>to</strong>rs and debt titles <strong>of</strong> about 85<br />

developing countries. Over time, <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se debt relief practices underwent<br />

significant changes. Table 2.1, which serves as <strong>the</strong> starting point for this section, provides a<br />

schematic overview <strong>of</strong> international debt relief initiatives and <strong>the</strong>ir specific modalities,<br />

organised by type <strong>of</strong> credi<strong>to</strong>r and identifying three (partly overlapping) phases or<br />

‘generations’: <strong>the</strong> pre-HIPC era, <strong>the</strong> HIPC Initiative itself and those initiatives that go<br />

beyond HIPC 7 . In <strong>the</strong> following subsections, each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se debt relief generations will be<br />

briefly discussed in turn.<br />

6 Usually because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> realisation <strong>of</strong> external transfer risk, in which <strong>the</strong> original deb<strong>to</strong>r did provide <strong>the</strong><br />

debt service payments in local currency, but <strong>the</strong> monetary authorities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> country could not assure him<br />

<strong>the</strong> foreign exchange <strong>to</strong> make <strong>the</strong> hard-currency transfer.<br />

7 The HIPC Initiative was chosen as a point <strong>of</strong> reference because <strong>of</strong> its pivotal and still central role in<br />

international debt relief practice (see text).<br />

| 31 |

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!