27.03.2013 Views

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

| 98 |<br />

<strong>Debt</strong> relief policy and practice by Belgium<br />

3.3.1 The <strong>Belgian</strong> practice: pro-active versus reactive?<br />

In any case, Belgium as a whole has been supportive from <strong>the</strong> beginning in joining <strong>the</strong><br />

international consensus that debt relief and cancellation was a necessary ingredient <strong>of</strong><br />

solving <strong>the</strong> problems debt overhang in severely-indebted lower income countries. More<br />

particularly, on bilateral state loans, we already highlighted <strong>the</strong> decision <strong>to</strong> cancel a range<br />

<strong>of</strong> bilateral loans <strong>to</strong> Toron<strong>to</strong>-eligible countries in 1990, early on. As such, for those claims,<br />

debt relief was ra<strong>the</strong>r frontloaded, avoiding repeated reschedulings, leading, eventually, <strong>to</strong><br />

high nominal debt relief later on, e.g. in <strong>the</strong> HIPC Initiative 72 .<br />

This quite pro-active <strong>Belgian</strong> stance in <strong>the</strong> Paris Club regarding bilateral loans was not<br />

readily shared when considering <strong>the</strong> ONDD claims. In fact, overall, <strong>the</strong> behaviour <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>Belgian</strong> regarding ONDD-claims in <strong>the</strong> Paris Club has been ra<strong>the</strong>r conservative, in <strong>the</strong><br />

sense that, when confronted <strong>with</strong> <strong>the</strong> policy space <strong>to</strong> choose between different options <strong>to</strong><br />

translate a common terms Paris Club agreement in<strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> bilateral agreement, Belgium,<br />

through <strong>the</strong> ONDD, <strong>of</strong>ten chose <strong>the</strong> option that kept <strong>the</strong> (nominal) value <strong>of</strong> claims at par:<br />

in <strong>the</strong> beginning, when one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> three options provided (<strong>the</strong> so-called B-option) allowed<br />

for a mere rescheduling at market terms, involving no element <strong>of</strong> debt relief in PV terms,<br />

on frequent occasions, <strong>the</strong> bilateral agreement between ONDD and <strong>the</strong> recipient country<br />

opted for this rescheduling option B, ra<strong>the</strong>r than for one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r two options involving<br />

an element <strong>of</strong> debt relief (in present value, PV, terms); this was <strong>the</strong> case until this option<br />

was abolished in December 1991, when <strong>the</strong> Paris Club adopted <strong>the</strong> Trinidad terms 73 . From<br />

<strong>the</strong>n onward, confronted <strong>with</strong> <strong>the</strong> choice between debt service relief (long rescheduling<br />

periods and concessional interest rates) and debt s<strong>to</strong>ck relief (a reduction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>of</strong><br />

debt), which do provide an equivalent amount <strong>of</strong> debt relief in PV terms, Belgium, through<br />

<strong>the</strong> ONDD decision, systematically chose <strong>the</strong> first option, leaving <strong>the</strong> nominal debt s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

intact. In order <strong>to</strong> come <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> - gradually increasing - required debt relief in PV terms,<br />

where possible <strong>with</strong>in <strong>the</strong> Paris Club framework, <strong>the</strong> ONDD used a policy <strong>of</strong> leng<strong>the</strong>ning<br />

repayment periods, reduced interest rates fur<strong>the</strong>r (sometimes at 0%), and/or made<br />

repayments <strong>of</strong> capital progressive over time 74 . On <strong>the</strong> issue <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> particular choice<br />

between debt service and debt s<strong>to</strong>ck relief, ONDD claims that it opted for <strong>the</strong> debt service<br />

relief option because and when it was not allowed by <strong>the</strong> <strong>Belgian</strong> government <strong>to</strong> opt for <strong>the</strong><br />

debt s<strong>to</strong>ck option 75 .<br />

The compensation agreement <strong>of</strong> 1991 (assessed in section 3.3.3) did <strong>of</strong>fer DGD an<br />

opportunity <strong>to</strong> become pro-actively involved in <strong>the</strong> debt relief field, through <strong>the</strong> swaps<br />

window. DGD had shown interest in doing debt swaps before <strong>the</strong> agreement (by doing<br />

72 As again highlighted in <strong>the</strong> next section, although important in nominal terms, however, in economic value<br />

terms, this debt relief can be considered quite negligible.<br />

73 In fact it was maintained as an exception for countries, essentially <strong>the</strong> United States, who did not want, or<br />

legally could not, proceed <strong>with</strong> debt relief.<br />

74 An extreme example is <strong>the</strong> Cameroon VI case, where part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> repayment <strong>of</strong> principal was stretched out<br />

in <strong>the</strong> distant future as a bullet repayment <strong>to</strong> be made in 2124; see section 4.2.1.<br />

75 Although <strong>the</strong> debt service and debt s<strong>to</strong>ck option have indeed <strong>to</strong> be considered equal in a PV sense, from<br />

<strong>the</strong> perspective <strong>of</strong> Belgium, and <strong>the</strong> ONDD, <strong>the</strong> fact that accounting rules (and <strong>the</strong> concrete set up <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

compensation agreements) focus on nominal debt s<strong>to</strong>ck concepts made this option more interesting from<br />

<strong>the</strong> ONDD perspective. See again section 3.3.3.<br />

<strong>Coming</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>Terms</strong> <strong>with</strong> <strong>Reality</strong><br />

some au<strong>to</strong>nomous swaps, even at full nominal value) and <strong>the</strong> agreement indirectly<br />

provided a good opportunity <strong>to</strong> design an active debt swaps policy, for which Belgium<br />

(<strong>to</strong>ge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>with</strong> e.g. Switzerland) was complimented internationally in <strong>the</strong> early 90s. The<br />

swap window might have created additional debt relief for <strong>the</strong> recipient countries (or, as<br />

stated earlier, ra<strong>the</strong>r frontloaded debt relief that would have taken place later on in <strong>the</strong><br />

context <strong>of</strong> HIPC), and additional ODA for Belgium. In principle this could be targeted<br />

<strong>to</strong>wards <strong>the</strong> priorities and partner countries <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Belgian</strong> development cooperation. 76<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, as debt claims could be acquired at a discount, a leverage effect seemed <strong>to</strong> be<br />

created. Again, in <strong>the</strong> next section, we will assess this debt swap policy.<br />

Did Belgium become more pro-active in <strong>the</strong> last decade, from <strong>the</strong> emergence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

HIPC-initiative on? The <strong>Belgian</strong> representatives in <strong>the</strong> Bret<strong>to</strong>n Woods institutions were<br />

definitely active participants in <strong>the</strong> debate on <strong>the</strong> scheme, but design continued <strong>to</strong> be<br />

dominated by <strong>the</strong> big international players, at <strong>the</strong> G7/G8 summits. Once accepted, Belgium<br />

was again very supportive in implementing <strong>the</strong> scheme: it was fully supportive in <strong>the</strong><br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> HIPC approach <strong>with</strong> respect <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> bilateral claims in <strong>the</strong> Paris Club,<br />

and engaged also in o<strong>the</strong>r debt relief interventions linked <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> HIPC Initiative, such as<br />

(voluntary) HIPC Trust Fund contributions, <strong>to</strong> support <strong>the</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> HIPC<br />

Initiative by regional development banks. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, for Burundi, it provided a bridge<br />

loan <strong>to</strong> allow <strong>the</strong> country <strong>to</strong> clear its arrears <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> IMF, helping in fulfilling one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

requirements in order <strong>to</strong> become eligible for HIPC treatment.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, Belgium joined <strong>the</strong> EU proposal in deciding <strong>to</strong> go beyond HIPC Cologne<br />

terms and move <strong>to</strong> full cancellation <strong>of</strong> its remaining eligible claims at HIPC completion<br />

point. The same goes for <strong>the</strong> design and implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> MDRI. However, in this<br />

case, most particularly, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Belgian</strong> Bret<strong>to</strong>n Woods representation (and especially <strong>the</strong> IMF<br />

representation) played a very active role, stressing <strong>the</strong> necessity for equal treatment for<br />

some non-eligible countries, and advocated for a stronger ex-ante check before granting<br />

actual completion point countries <strong>the</strong> extra debt relief 77 .<br />

After 2000, Belgium decided on debt relief beyond <strong>the</strong> Paris Club agreements for two<br />

countries: <strong>the</strong> Democratic Republic <strong>of</strong> Congo (DRC) and <strong>the</strong> Seychelles. The DRC had<br />

reached its decision point in <strong>the</strong> framework <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> HIPC Initiative in 2003. In <strong>the</strong> same<br />

year, Belgium cancelled unilaterally more than 50% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ONDD claims on DRC. This<br />

decision was taken jointly by ONDD and DGD and went fur<strong>the</strong>r than, but was still<br />

conform <strong>to</strong>, <strong>the</strong> Paris Club agreement. DGD participated in this operation by allowing <strong>the</strong><br />

76 However, DGD claims that, in practice, it had very little leverage on choosing <strong>the</strong> countries on which <strong>to</strong> do<br />

swaps. Typically a limited list <strong>of</strong> potential claims eligible for swaps was presented <strong>to</strong> DGD by ONDD.<br />

77 Regarding <strong>the</strong> design <strong>of</strong> new initiatives, Belgium <strong>to</strong>ok one particular initiative when <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n Prime<br />

Minister Mr. Verh<strong>of</strong>stadt presented <strong>the</strong> PAIR proposal (see Berlage et al 2003) as a <strong>Belgian</strong> debt relief<br />

proposal a.o. at <strong>the</strong> Monterrey ‘Financing for Development’ Summit in 2001.<br />

| 99 |

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!