27.03.2013 Views

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

| 70 |<br />

International debt relief initiatives and <strong>the</strong>ir effects<br />

following debt relief). Conversely, Dömeland and Kharas (2009) argue that <strong>the</strong> HIPC Initiative<br />

has nei<strong>the</strong>r resulted in a greater net transfer <strong>of</strong> resources <strong>to</strong> participating countries, nor caused a<br />

major shift from donor resources <strong>to</strong>ward HIPCs away from non-HIPCs. They maintain that <strong>the</strong><br />

initiative may have simply prevented a decline in resource flows <strong>to</strong> HIPCs that were facing high<br />

debt service obligations before. The validity <strong>of</strong> this counterfactual is however difficult <strong>to</strong> assess.<br />

Governance<br />

Also regarding <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> debt relief as an instrument for rewarding ex post institution<br />

building <strong>of</strong> countries, it looks like <strong>the</strong>re have been some improvements over <strong>the</strong> years.<br />

Dömeland and Kharas (2009) graphically show that, on average, gains in HIPCs’ policy<br />

and institutional quality become apparent three years before <strong>the</strong> reaching <strong>of</strong> completion<br />

point and continue for some years <strong>the</strong>reafter. Depetris Chauvin and Kraay (2007), which<br />

examine <strong>the</strong> fac<strong>to</strong>rs underlying debt relief allocation <strong>to</strong> 62 low-income countries, discover<br />

that 1999-2003 debt relief, in particular that by multilateral credi<strong>to</strong>rs, responded positively<br />

<strong>to</strong> higher deb<strong>to</strong>r country policy and institutional ratings (more than aid did), although <strong>the</strong>re<br />

appeared <strong>to</strong> be some ‘path dependency’ 43 in debt relief incidence among countries.<br />

Similarly, Freytag and Pehnelt (2009) report for a sample <strong>of</strong> 123 developing countries that,<br />

while changes in governance ratings seemed uncorrelated <strong>with</strong> HIPC debt relief eligibility,<br />

<strong>the</strong> amounts <strong>of</strong> debt relief granted in 2000-2004 were positively associated <strong>with</strong><br />

improvements in countries’ governance quality. In addition, HIPCs which improve on <strong>the</strong><br />

rule <strong>of</strong> law, government effectiveness and control <strong>of</strong> corruption (all dimensions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

quality <strong>of</strong> country governance) are found <strong>to</strong> reach completion point earlier than those that<br />

perform worse in <strong>the</strong>se domains. Presbitero (2009) largely corroborates <strong>the</strong>se findings<br />

using 1988-2007 debt relief figures, but denounces <strong>the</strong> hypo<strong>the</strong>sis that causality also runs<br />

in <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r direction, from debt relief in one period <strong>to</strong> improved governance in <strong>the</strong> next.<br />

2.5.2.2 Effectiveness<br />

<strong>Debt</strong> sustainability<br />

As indicated before, debt relief provision is futile if <strong>the</strong> whole process <strong>of</strong> countries<br />

amassing unsustainable levels <strong>of</strong> debt starts all over again <strong>the</strong>reafter. To avoid renewed<br />

unsustainable debt accumulation, <strong>the</strong> IMF, which carries out debt sustainability analyses<br />

(DSAs) <strong>of</strong> countries’ external and public debt on a regular basis, <strong>to</strong>ge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>with</strong> <strong>the</strong> World<br />

Bank launched <strong>the</strong> joint <strong>Debt</strong> Sustainability Framework (DSF) for low-income countries in<br />

2005 (see section 2.2.1). The overall objective <strong>of</strong> this framework has been <strong>to</strong> govern<br />

prospective lending decisions (<strong>to</strong> finance <strong>the</strong> MDGs) while preventing <strong>the</strong> need for ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

future round <strong>of</strong> systemic debt relief. The DSF compares debt burden indica<strong>to</strong>rs, such as<br />

e.g. NPV debt-<strong>to</strong>-export ratios, <strong>with</strong> indicative thresholds over a 20-year projection period<br />

<strong>to</strong> assess <strong>the</strong> debt sustainability <strong>of</strong> individual countries. On <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong> such comparisons,<br />

additional stress tests and taking in<strong>to</strong> account differences in policy performance, countries<br />

are <strong>the</strong>n rated and categorised as bearing low risk, moderate risk, high risk or as being in<br />

debt distress (when debt repayment difficulties are already present) (see IMF, 2010d).<br />

43 Path dependency means here that debt relief patterns were driven by fairly persistent country characteristics,<br />

<strong>with</strong> countries receiving debt relief in a certain time period more likely <strong>to</strong> also receive it in <strong>the</strong> next period.<br />

<strong>Coming</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>Terms</strong> <strong>with</strong> <strong>Reality</strong><br />

Beddies et al. (2009) suggest that HIPC and MDRI debt relief has significantly improved<br />

debt sustainability when <strong>the</strong>y indicate that, at end-2007, post-completion HIPCs on<br />

average had a rosier debt outlook and lower risk <strong>of</strong> debt distress than o<strong>the</strong>r HIPCs and<br />

low-income non-HIPCs. In a recent report <strong>the</strong> IMF and <strong>the</strong> World Bank fur<strong>the</strong>rmore note<br />

that <strong>the</strong> 2007-2009 global financial and economic crisis, although certainly having a<br />

significant impact on low-income countries’ debt vulnerabilities, is not expected <strong>to</strong> translate<br />

in new systemic debt difficulties (see IMF and World Bank, 2010). These contentions<br />

however assume a non-permanent impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> crisis on long-term growth and substantial<br />

country efforts <strong>to</strong> speed up policy and institutional enhancement. This may well turn out <strong>to</strong><br />

be overly optimistic 44 . Leo (2009) points out that IMF and World Bank projections for GDP<br />

and export growth in HIPCs, which serve as inputs in<strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> DSF, have proven <strong>to</strong> be<br />

structurally higher than actual and his<strong>to</strong>rical economic performance 45 . He fur<strong>the</strong>r urges<br />

caution when using country policy performance measures, as <strong>the</strong>y continue <strong>to</strong> be volatile for<br />

a number <strong>of</strong> HIPCs.<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r point <strong>of</strong> importance is that, despite a relative shift <strong>to</strong> more grant funding, new<br />

lending volumes disbursed <strong>to</strong> HIPCs remain large in absolute terms, approximating<br />

pre-MDRI levels (Leo, 2009). Indeed, <strong>the</strong>re seems <strong>to</strong> be some sort <strong>of</strong> tension between <strong>the</strong><br />

MDG-PRSP logic, i.e. financing national development strategies <strong>of</strong> low-income countries <strong>to</strong><br />

support <strong>the</strong>ir progress <strong>to</strong>wards <strong>the</strong> MDGs, and guaranteeing debt sustainability in those<br />

countries (thus avoiding new debt relief). Solving this tension starts <strong>with</strong> adhering <strong>to</strong> a<br />

framework for responsible borrowing and lending, as advocated by, among o<strong>the</strong>rs, UNCTAD<br />

and <strong>the</strong> OECD 46 (see e.g. Buchheit and Gulati, 2009 and OECD, 2008). It is argued that, on<br />

<strong>the</strong> one hand, lenders <strong>to</strong> sovereign borrowers should show due diligence in investigating <strong>the</strong><br />

(intended) use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> financing <strong>the</strong>y make available prior <strong>to</strong> (as well as after) disbursement <strong>of</strong><br />

funds. In <strong>the</strong> past, all <strong>to</strong>o <strong>of</strong>ten governments have been held <strong>to</strong> honour <strong>the</strong> debts contracted<br />

by <strong>the</strong>ir irresponsible predecessors or (military) dicta<strong>to</strong>rs 47 . On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, borrowing<br />

countries should proceed <strong>with</strong> restraint and prudence, and disclose all information necessary<br />

for lenders <strong>to</strong> make informed credit decisions (Buchheit and Gulati, 2009).<br />

<strong>Debt</strong> overhang elimination and creditworthiness<br />

In accordance <strong>with</strong> debt overhang <strong>the</strong>ory, Cassimon and Van Campenhout (2007) provide<br />

evidence <strong>of</strong> a positive trend in HIPC government investment (i.e. capital expenditure) in<br />

<strong>the</strong> years following debt forgiveness (<strong>with</strong> a certain time lag or j-curve effect). Cassimon<br />

and Van Campenhout (2008) largely confirm this result for a sample <strong>of</strong> African HIPCs and<br />

a longer time interval. Both studies remain however vigilant in acknowledging that this is<br />

only an average trend which cannot be generalised <strong>to</strong> hold for all HIPCs. One exceptional<br />

44 UNCTAD (2009), for example, presents a grimmer picture <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> crisis on debt sustainability<br />

in developing countries.<br />

45 This compares <strong>to</strong> an underestimation <strong>of</strong> growth figures for low-income non-HIPCs (Leo, 2009).<br />

46 The OECD primarily focuses on sustainable lending practices in <strong>the</strong> provision <strong>of</strong> (commercial) export<br />

credits <strong>to</strong> low-income countries, whereas UNCTAD considers <strong>the</strong> broader responsibilities <strong>of</strong> sovereign<br />

borrowers and lenders. In Belgium, <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial export credit agency ONDD adheres <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> international<br />

(OECD) standards on sustainable lending.<br />

47 See e.g. World Bank (2007) for more information about such ‘regime debts’ or o<strong>the</strong>r instances <strong>of</strong> ‘odious debt’.<br />

| 71 |

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!