27.03.2013 Views

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

Coming to Terms with Reality. Evaluation of the Belgian Debt Relief ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

| 104 |<br />

<strong>Debt</strong> relief policy and practice by Belgium<br />

contribution by DGD <strong>with</strong> <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal compensation required for ONDD. 81<br />

Inspired by <strong>the</strong> relevant scientific literature, in section 2.2.2.2 we have proposed that debt<br />

relief should be assessed from an ‘economic value’ perspective, i.e. <strong>the</strong> concept that refers<br />

<strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> debt (service) payments that would have been made by <strong>the</strong> deb<strong>to</strong>r, in this case <strong>to</strong><br />

ONDD, in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> debt relief (formula 1 on p.21). We believe that this starting<br />

point is uncontroversial and unassailable. In fact, what ONDD is requesting as <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

compensation, and what determines <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> compensation agreements <strong>of</strong> 1991,<br />

2001 and 2005, is based on <strong>the</strong> same underlying principles. The real question is how<br />

exactly <strong>to</strong> apply this concept in practice. As we have already outlined in section 2.2.2.2, in<br />

our understanding, four elements are crucial here: (1) whe<strong>the</strong>r we use nominal versus<br />

NPV <strong>of</strong> debt, (2) <strong>the</strong> determination <strong>of</strong> ‘i’ (<strong>the</strong> discount rate in formula 1) when using NPV,<br />

(3) <strong>the</strong> determination <strong>of</strong> ‘d’ (<strong>the</strong> default rate), and (4) <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> default rate ‘d’ in<br />

marginal versus comprehensive debt relief operations. We will turn <strong>to</strong> each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se<br />

elements in more detail below, from <strong>the</strong> perspective <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> concrete compensation<br />

agreements.<br />

(1) Nominal versus NPV <strong>of</strong> debt. It is widely accepted in <strong>the</strong> literature, and put in practice<br />

in international debt rescheduling and relief initiatives (Paris Club, IMF/World Bank<br />

HIPC), that <strong>the</strong> (N)PV is <strong>the</strong> correct approach <strong>to</strong> calculate <strong>the</strong> economic value <strong>of</strong> debt<br />

relief, and <strong>to</strong> determine fair burden sharing. However, <strong>the</strong> debt base that is underlying<br />

both <strong>the</strong> 1991 and 2001, 2005 agreements is <strong>the</strong> nominal s<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>of</strong> debt (relieved). Clearly,<br />

this is also because current accounting standards at ONDD are based on nominal value.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>y are, and that accounting losses <strong>of</strong> ONDD are based on nominal<br />

value, and so required compensation by ONDD takes that same base, does not mean that<br />

<strong>the</strong> validity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> NPV approach would collapse. If anything, <strong>the</strong> reverse is <strong>the</strong> case. In<br />

fact, <strong>the</strong> accounting value <strong>of</strong> a financial asset should reflect its economic value, i.e. <strong>the</strong><br />

present value <strong>of</strong> its future income streams. This is indeed <strong>the</strong> case when assets earn a<br />

market return, because <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>ir nominal value is a good approximation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> present<br />

value. However, for concessional claims this does not hold, suggesting that nominal<br />

(accounting) values are not appropriate. Moreover, it is not only that nominal values fail <strong>to</strong><br />

express present values in this case, it is also that <strong>the</strong>ir use in compensation formulas can<br />

easily lead <strong>to</strong> moral hazard. Take <strong>the</strong> case where nominal value exceeds NPV. A credi<strong>to</strong>r<br />

would <strong>the</strong>n be tempted <strong>to</strong> keep <strong>the</strong> nominal value <strong>of</strong> its claims intact as long as possible,<br />

e.g. by granting a required discount, expressed in NPV terms, by stretching out principal<br />

repayments <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> very distant future, even if this option is damaging <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> recipient. In<br />

NPV terms, <strong>the</strong> value’s claim would be reduced by <strong>the</strong> agreed upon discount, but at <strong>the</strong><br />

same time it would remain valued at 100% in nominal value. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, a credit<br />

agency has an incentive <strong>to</strong> select an option that it knows is less favourable <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> recipient,<br />

but that maximises <strong>the</strong> compensation <strong>the</strong> agency hopes <strong>to</strong> receive. This is exactly what<br />

Belgium (ONDD) did in <strong>the</strong> Cameroon case. A good valuation system and compensation<br />

81 To <strong>the</strong> extent that full compensation is deemed legitimate, after compensation from DGD on <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> principles that we have set out, <strong>the</strong> remaining financing gap should be filled by ano<strong>the</strong>r government<br />

budget; as export credits are typically a foreign trade policy instrument, <strong>the</strong> foreign trade budget is likely<br />

<strong>to</strong> be <strong>the</strong> most natural candidate.<br />

<strong>Coming</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>Terms</strong> <strong>with</strong> <strong>Reality</strong><br />

formula should be constructed so as <strong>to</strong> avoid such moral hazard behaviour up-front; this<br />

can be done by explicitly using <strong>the</strong> NPV logic in <strong>the</strong> approach, similar <strong>to</strong> what is common<br />

practice in debt relief burden sharing calculations in <strong>the</strong> IMF, World Bank and Paris Club.<br />

To conclude, as such, <strong>to</strong> determine a fair compensation from a development perspective,<br />

<strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> debt relieved should be calculated at its PV.<br />

(2) The determination <strong>of</strong> ‘i’ (<strong>the</strong> discount rate) when using NPV. Since we are using a PV<br />

concept, we have <strong>to</strong> derive <strong>the</strong> appropriate discount rate. In section 2.2.2.2 we discussed<br />

this in more detail, stating our preference-in-principle for a deb<strong>to</strong>r-based recipient<br />

country-specific discount rate, but accepting, in line <strong>with</strong> <strong>the</strong> concepts <strong>of</strong> measuring aid<br />

efficiency (developed in table 2.11), and more specifically <strong>the</strong> ‘economic cost’ perspective<br />

that we suggest here, <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> a credi<strong>to</strong>r-specific discount rate. As such, in calculating<br />

<strong>the</strong> economic value <strong>of</strong> debt relief from a development perspective, we could settle for <strong>the</strong><br />

CIRR being a relatively good proxy <strong>of</strong> a credi<strong>to</strong>r-specific interest rate that is<br />

internationally-agreed upon, <strong>to</strong> be used in <strong>the</strong> calculations, instead <strong>of</strong> a deb<strong>to</strong>r-specific<br />

domestic interest rate, which is most likely higher than <strong>the</strong> CIRR.<br />

(3) The determination <strong>of</strong> ‘d’ (<strong>the</strong> default rate). Thirdly, as again stressed in section 2.2.2.2,<br />

<strong>the</strong> PV <strong>of</strong> debt relief should be corrected <strong>to</strong> account for default risk, leading <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> notion<br />

<strong>of</strong> economic value as we have defined it. We also discussed that, in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> an<br />

international benchmark scoring model <strong>to</strong> derive <strong>the</strong> default risk, an accepted credi<strong>to</strong>rspecific<br />

scoring model, such as <strong>the</strong> one used by ONDD, despite its lack <strong>of</strong> transparency,<br />

could be a satisfac<strong>to</strong>ry proxy. It is important <strong>to</strong> stress here that both <strong>the</strong> agreements <strong>of</strong><br />

1991, and those <strong>of</strong> 2001 and 2005 do explicitly account for default risk, on <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong><br />

scoring model <strong>of</strong> ONDD exactly. This means that <strong>to</strong> derive an appropriate economic value<br />

<strong>of</strong> debt relief from a development perspective, for debt relief granted through large scale,<br />

comprehensive debt relief operations (only), default risk is appropriately proxied by <strong>the</strong><br />

default risk scores from ONDD’s internal scoring model. Consequently, <strong>the</strong> default risk<br />

measure that is suggested in <strong>the</strong> 2001 and 2005 compensation agreements is identical <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> one appropriate from a development perspective.<br />

(4) The use <strong>of</strong> ‘d’ in marginal versus comprehensive debt relief operations. Finally, <strong>the</strong><br />

discussion from section 2.2.2.2 also highlighted <strong>the</strong> inappropriateness <strong>of</strong> using <strong>the</strong> ‘d’ as<br />

derived from scoring models such as <strong>the</strong> one used by ONDD, in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> valuing debt<br />

relief operations where <strong>the</strong> debt relief treats an amount <strong>of</strong> debt that is very small<br />

(‘marginal’) compared <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal debt s<strong>to</strong>ck. The reason is that <strong>the</strong> ‘d’ derived in scoring<br />

models denotes <strong>the</strong> ‘on average’ default rate, <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> whole debt s<strong>to</strong>ck. For debt-ridden<br />

countries, <strong>the</strong> average value is not a good indica<strong>to</strong>r <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> default rate on <strong>the</strong> last unit <strong>of</strong><br />

debt service that would have been paid (<strong>the</strong> marginal value). As <strong>the</strong> marginal value <strong>of</strong> debt<br />

is always higher than <strong>the</strong> average value <strong>of</strong> debt, or in o<strong>the</strong>r words <strong>the</strong> average ‘d’ always<br />

smaller than <strong>the</strong> marginal ´d´, basing a valuation or compensation formula for small<br />

(‘marginal’) debt relief operations, say small buybacks, debt swaps, or debt flow<br />

rescheduling as in <strong>the</strong> Paris Club, on this average ‘d’ as derived from such scoring models<br />

(reflected in secondary market prices for debt) would overstate <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> debt relief<br />

and result in a requested compensation that is higher than what would be <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> debt<br />

| 105 |

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!