04.11.2014 Views

cyckV4

cyckV4

cyckV4

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

314 COPYRIGHTABLE SUBJECT MATTER<br />

2.) Judge Sweet focuses on the could—a user could “push a button or two and obtain<br />

West’s exact selection and arrangement.” But a user could also push “a button or two” and<br />

arrange the cases by alphabetical ordering of case name, of defendant’s name(s), of<br />

judge’s name, of day of the week, of the type of law being decided, or any of a hundred<br />

more possible methods. Judge Sweet says “[t]his technological capacity presents a new<br />

question. The majority’s answer threatens to eviscerate copyright protection for compilations.”<br />

But if many forms of ordering, selection or arrangement can be cybernetically<br />

imposed, by software, on a mass of material dumped, unordered, on a hard drive or DVD,<br />

does Judge Sweet’s answer not bring up an opposite problem? All compilations could<br />

potentially be “immanent within,” implicitly present within, the database. Does that therefore<br />

mean that any system for flexibly arranging data inherently violates compilation<br />

copyrights on all of the arrangements it could be used to emulate?<br />

James Boyle: A Natural Experiment<br />

Financial Times, Nov 22, 2004<br />

Imagine a process of reviewing prescription drugs which goes like this:<br />

representatives from the drug company come to the regulators and argue that their drug<br />

works well and should be approved. They have no evidence of this beyond a few anecdotes<br />

about people who want to take it and perhaps some very simple models of how the drug<br />

might affect the human body. The drug is approved. No trials, no empirical evidence of<br />

any kind, no follow-up. Or imagine a process of making environmental regulations in<br />

which there were no data, and no attempts to gather data, about the effects of the particular<br />

pollutants being studied. Even the harshest critics of drug regulation or environmental<br />

regulation would admit we generally do better than this. But this is often the way we make<br />

intellectual property policy.<br />

So how do we decide the ground-rules of the information age? Representatives of<br />

interested industries come to regulators and ask for another heaping slice of monopoly<br />

rent in the form of an intellectual property right. They have doom-laden predictions, they<br />

have anecdotes, carefully selected to pluck the heartstrings of legislators, they have<br />

celebrities who testify—often incoherently, but with palpable charisma—and they have<br />

very, very simple economic models. The basic economic model here is “If you give me<br />

a larger right, I will have a larger incentive to innovate. Thus the bigger the rights, the<br />

more innovation we will get. Right?” Well, not exactly. Even without data, the models<br />

are obviously flawed—copyrighting the alphabet will not produce more books, patenting<br />

E=mc 2 will not yield more scientific innovation. Intellectual property creates barriers to,<br />

as well as incentives towards, innovation. Clearly the “more is better” argument has<br />

limits. Extensions of rights can help or hurt, but without economic evidence beforehand<br />

and review afterwards, we will never know. In the absence of evidence on either side,<br />

the presumption should obviously be against creating a new legalised monopoly, but still<br />

the empirical emptiness of the debates is frustrating.<br />

This makes the occasion where there actually is some evidence a time for<br />

celebration. What we really need is a test case where one country adopts the proposed<br />

new intellectual property right and another does not, and we can assess how they are both<br />

doing after a number of years.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!