02.12.2012 Views

Applications of state space models in finance

Applications of state space models in finance

Applications of state space models in finance

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

A.3 Alternative asset pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>models</strong> 161<br />

Factor pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>models</strong> specify the stochastic discount factor as a l<strong>in</strong>ear function <strong>of</strong> the<br />

form<br />

m = a + b ′ f, (A.6)<br />

with free parameters a and b. The K × 1 vector <strong>of</strong> factors f is chosen as a proxy for<br />

an <strong>in</strong>vestor’s marg<strong>in</strong>al utility growth. As demonstrated by Cochrane (2005, ¢ 6), (A.6)<br />

is equivalent to a multiple-beta model <strong>of</strong> expected returns:<br />

E(Ri) = γ + λ ′ β i, (A.7)<br />

with the K × 1 vector β i conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the multiple regression coefficients <strong>of</strong> returns Ri on<br />

f for assets i = 1, . . . , N. This specification, usually referred to as a beta pric<strong>in</strong>g model,<br />

<strong>state</strong>s that each expected return is proportional to the asset specific β i, which is also<br />

known as the quantity <strong>of</strong> risk. The k × 1 vector <strong>of</strong> free parameters λ, which is the same<br />

for all assets i, can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as the price <strong>of</strong> risk. In a world with exist<strong>in</strong>g risk-free<br />

assets, i.e. a zero-beta portfolio, the constant γ is usually assumed to be equal to the<br />

risk-free <strong>in</strong>terest rate, denoted by r f ; the economic model <strong>in</strong> (A.7) can be written <strong>in</strong><br />

terms <strong>of</strong> returns <strong>in</strong> excess <strong>of</strong> the risk-free rate with γ be<strong>in</strong>g set to zero.<br />

In order to identify the factors f that can serve as appropriate proxies for marg<strong>in</strong>al<br />

utility growth, one looks for variables for which (A.6) approximately holds. As consumption<br />

is economically l<strong>in</strong>ked to the <strong>state</strong> <strong>of</strong> the economy, macroeconomic variables,<br />

such as <strong>in</strong>terest rates, GDP growth and broad-based portfolios, constitute the first set <strong>of</strong><br />

factors. Consumption can be assumed to also depend on current newsflow that signals<br />

future <strong>in</strong>come and consumption changes. Variables that either <strong>in</strong>dicate changes <strong>in</strong> consumption<br />

and/ or other macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>dicators, or predict asset returns directly, also<br />

qualify as potential factors; important variables <strong>in</strong>clude dividend yields, stock returns<br />

or the term premium (Cochrane 2005, ¢ 9).<br />

The most important factor pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>models</strong> <strong>in</strong>clude the s<strong>in</strong>gle-factor Capital Asset<br />

Pric<strong>in</strong>g Model (CAPM), the Intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) and the Arbitrage Pric<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Theory (APT). The latter two allow for multiple sources <strong>of</strong> systematic risk. They all<br />

represent specializations <strong>of</strong> the consumption-based model, <strong>in</strong> which extra assumptions<br />

allow for the use <strong>of</strong> other variables to proxy for marg<strong>in</strong>al utility growth. They can be<br />

summarized as follows:<br />

The CAPM, developed by Sharpe (1964) and L<strong>in</strong>tner (1965), is the first and still<br />

most widely used factor pric<strong>in</strong>g model. It l<strong>in</strong>early relates the expected return <strong>of</strong><br />

an asset to the return’s covariance with the return on the wealth portfolio. The<br />

return on total wealth is usually approximated by the return on a broad-market<br />

stock portfolio.<br />

The ICAPM by Merton (1973) is grounded on equilibrium arguments where an<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestor tries to hedge uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty about future returns by demand<strong>in</strong>g assets that<br />

do well on bad news. In equilibrium, expected returns depend on the covariation<br />

with current market returns and on the covariation with news that predict changes<br />

<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>vestment opportunity set <strong>of</strong> an <strong>in</strong>vestor. The ICAPM can be represented<br />

by (A.6) where each <strong>state</strong> variable that forecasts future market returns can be a<br />

factor.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!