30.06.2013 Views

TESTING INTERNATIONAL PRICE TRANSMISSION UNDER ...

TESTING INTERNATIONAL PRICE TRANSMISSION UNDER ...

TESTING INTERNATIONAL PRICE TRANSMISSION UNDER ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Price Transmission and the Law of One Price<br />

2.3 A theoretical problem: why should the LOP hold?<br />

The previous paragraph provides a general outline of the fundamental<br />

theoretical concepts relative to price transmission analysis. As it will be clearer in<br />

chapter 3, where the empirical models which have been used for the study of price<br />

transmission are presented, what emerges is a controversial picture. Indeed, not<br />

only are even the basic definitions not fully agreed upon researchers, but<br />

empirical analysis has brought a very mixed evidence (see annex A for a review).<br />

In this paragraph, some concluding remarks concerning the reliability of the<br />

LOP hypothesis to hold in practice will be given, which might be the cause of the<br />

absence of empirical evidence supporting it. This issue is nonetheless strictly<br />

entangled, as we will see in chapter 3, to the underlying hypothesis and properties<br />

of the models used, and this is particularly true if they rely only on price data<br />

(paragraph 3.4).<br />

It is well recognized that, though denoting this concept a “law” reflects the<br />

considerable faith in its adherence (Fackler and Goodwin 2001, p.977), the<br />

simplicity of the LOP can be easily questioned, as its assumptions prove to be<br />

quite restrictive and unlikely to hold in practice. Williamson (1986 cited Fackler<br />

and Goodwin 2001, p.975) and Miljkovic (1999, p.126) note that the LOP has<br />

been violated by empirical tests probably more than any other economic laws.<br />

The LOP is expected to regulate spatial price relations in a frictionless<br />

undistorted world; the premises of full price transmission and market integration<br />

correspond to those of the standard competition model (Conforti 2004, p.1).<br />

Following Miljkovic (1999) and Conforti (2004), some major groups of factors<br />

that prevent prices from convergence can be identified 12 .<br />

Transaction costs play a crucial role while investigating market efficiency, and<br />

this is particularly important in agriculture, since they are relevant if compared to<br />

the value of the commodities considered (Fackler and Goodwin 2001, p.973;<br />

Barrett 2001, p.27). Unless certain assumptions are made, their treatment is not<br />

easy; and, even if the LOP is satisfied, if transaction costs are large and volatile,<br />

prices don’t move together. Transaction costs have many components. In addition<br />

to the very transport costs (normally, freight rates, i.e. per unit transportation<br />

costs), we also have variable transport costs (insurance, financing, hedging,<br />

contracting, technical barriers to trade), exogenous costs components<br />

(underwriting fees, testing charges), unit average duties, and other immeasurable<br />

transaction costs (such as search costs and exchange rate variability; Barrett 2001,<br />

p.23); in other words, all other information, negotiation, monitoring and<br />

enforcement costs (Williamson cited Conforti 2004, p.2). Linnemann (1996 cited<br />

12 In general, the conditions necessary for adherence to factor price equalization are even stronger than those<br />

required for output markets; evidence supporting factor market integration is weak (Fackler and Goodwin<br />

2001, p. 976).<br />

18

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!