30.06.2013 Views

TESTING INTERNATIONAL PRICE TRANSMISSION UNDER ...

TESTING INTERNATIONAL PRICE TRANSMISSION UNDER ...

TESTING INTERNATIONAL PRICE TRANSMISSION UNDER ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Empirical Tests for Spatial Price Analysis<br />

defined as the situation within, at or outside the arbitrage condition. Market<br />

efficiency is equivalent to the probability of the regime which satisfies the<br />

arbitrage condition to be one and the others to be zero. Baulch (1997) extends this<br />

model by adding explicit information on transaction costs and allowing trade flow<br />

reversals to take place. The use of this approach (called the Parity Bound Model)<br />

allows markets to be integrated in some periods but not in others (trade flows<br />

discontinuity), transfer costs to vary between periods, and prices to be<br />

contemporaneously determined.<br />

Indicating with P1 t − P2<br />

t the price differential, with C 12 the transfer cost, and<br />

with u It and u Ot the additional error terms inside and outside the parity bounds<br />

(assumed to be independently and half normally distributed), three regimes are<br />

derived according to the size of price spreads and of transfer costs:<br />

− P = C . Regime 1 – efficient arbitrage: the price differential is<br />

− P1 t 2t<br />

12<br />

exactly at the parity bound; transfer costs equal the market price differential<br />

and there are no impediments to trade between markets. Trade will cause<br />

prices to move on a one-to one basis and the arbitrage conditions are<br />

binding.<br />

P P = C − u . Regime 2 – the price differential is inside the parity<br />

− 1 t − 2t<br />

12 It<br />

bound. In this case, the interpretations of Baulch and Sexton et al. are<br />

slightly different. For Baulch, when the price differential is inside the parity<br />

bound, it is because transfer costs exceed the inter-market spread: trade will<br />

not occur and the arbitrage conditions will not be binding (no profitable<br />

trade flows). For Sexton et al., that assume unidirectional trade, if the price<br />

spread is within the arbitrage band it is because too much trade has occurred<br />

(“relative glut”).<br />

P P = C + u . Regime 3 – the price differential is outside the parity<br />

− 1 t − 2t<br />

12 Ot<br />

bound. In Baulch’s model, if spreads exceed transfer costs, the spatial<br />

arbitrage conditions are violated whether or not trade occurs (non exploited<br />

profitable trade opportunity). In the interpretation of Sexton et al., too little<br />

trade occurs (“relative shortage” case).<br />

In the switching regime models presented, the probability distribution<br />

associated with the price spread is a mixture of three distributions, corresponding<br />

to the three regimes. The logarithm of the likelihood function of the sample is<br />

minimized and gives probability estimates for each of the three regimes 23 : the<br />

extent of market integration is expressed in terms of a continuous frequency of<br />

23 If transfer costs were known, testing for the efficiency of spatial arbitrage would reduce to arithmetically<br />

calculate whether trade occurred or not whenever the inter-market price differential exceeded or not transfer<br />

costs. But time series data on transfer costs are rarely available: either they must be estimated and inserted in<br />

the model, or be an endogenous parameter (Sexton et al. 1991).<br />

33

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!