17.11.2012 Views

Entire Volume 17 issue 1 - Journal of World-Systems Research ...

Entire Volume 17 issue 1 - Journal of World-Systems Research ...

Entire Volume 17 issue 1 - Journal of World-Systems Research ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

119 JOURNAL OF WORLD-SYSTEMS RESEARCH<br />

comprehend that messy and evolving web <strong>of</strong> relations we call capitalism. In much the same<br />

fashion, the Nature/Society binary short-circuits research into the cumulatively- and cyclicallyevolving<br />

configurations <strong>of</strong> human and extra-human nature over the longue durée, including the<br />

movements <strong>of</strong> the present crisis.<br />

The problem with taking history seriously is that it “continually messes up the neat<br />

conceptual frameworks and the more or less elegant theoretical speculations” we’ve worked so<br />

hard to construct (Arrighi 2000:1<strong>17</strong>). The relation <strong>of</strong> theory and history is <strong>of</strong> course at the center<br />

<strong>of</strong> a vast literature in historical sociology, and I will not reprise the debates here. 12<br />

I do wish,<br />

however, to place the methodological and theoretical implications <strong>of</strong> Arrighi’s accounting <strong>of</strong><br />

historical capitalism into dialogue with the challenges <strong>of</strong> rethinking modernity as a socioecological<br />

process and project.<br />

If history has its way <strong>of</strong> “messing up” our models, how do we respond? We can begin<br />

with a reflexive approach to specificity, in two principal ways. The first involves the conceptualhistorical<br />

task; the second, a historical-conceptual challenge. We may consider these in turn.<br />

The conceptual-historical task implicates the reflexive interrogation <strong>of</strong> the relation<br />

between theory and history in successive phases <strong>of</strong> capitalist development. A concept <strong>of</strong><br />

imperialism appropriate to the analysis <strong>of</strong> world power in the <strong>17</strong> th century is unlikely to be<br />

adequate for explaining the “new imperialisms” <strong>of</strong> subsequent eras. 13 Arrighi <strong>of</strong>ten reminded<br />

students that while the signifier, “imperialism,” had remained constant over the 20 th century, the<br />

bundle <strong>of</strong> relations that it signified had changed substantially. 14<br />

This sensibility informs his first<br />

rule for the conceptual mapping <strong>of</strong> historical capitalism:<br />

The idea still dominant in world-system analysis <strong>of</strong> a quantitatively expanding<br />

but structurally invariant world capitalist system must be abandoned, including<br />

and especially the notion <strong>of</strong> Kondratieff cycles, hegemonic cycles, and logistics<br />

as empirical manifestations <strong>of</strong> such a structural invariance (2004:38).<br />

The temptations <strong>of</strong> “structural invariance” find traction beyond world-systems analysis.<br />

In the closely related field <strong>of</strong> world environmental history, commercialization <strong>of</strong>ten appears as a<br />

primary form <strong>of</strong> structural invariance, through which market forces inflict great damage to<br />

landscapes (e.g. Richards 2003; Hughes 2001). But this forgets that world markets are not created<br />

equal. The world market <strong>of</strong> the long 16 th century, and the world market today, are not only<br />

quantitatively, but also qualitatively variant. Conceptual specificity and empirical specificity are<br />

dialectically bound. There is, then, good reason – for environmental historians and world-systems<br />

analysts both – to revisit the kind <strong>of</strong> conceptual-historical sensibility Marx evinced in observing<br />

that “every particular historical mode <strong>of</strong> production has its own special laws <strong>of</strong> population”<br />

(1976:784). Can we not also include, alongside population, specific socio-ecological<br />

configurations <strong>of</strong> market exchange, industry, business enterprise, class structure, imperial power,<br />

and urbanization in successive eras <strong>of</strong> capitalism? This observation poses new questions<br />

12 Classic texts are Abrams (1982), Burke (1980), and Skocpol (1984).<br />

13 This is not to rule out the cross-fertilization <strong>of</strong> concepts. Consider Chase-Dunn and Hall’s classic work<br />

on comparing world-systems over the longue durée <strong>of</strong> civilization (1997).<br />

14 An argument Arrighi developed throughout his career (1978b, 2007, 2009).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!