17.11.2012 Views

Entire Volume 17 issue 1 - Journal of World-Systems Research ...

Entire Volume 17 issue 1 - Journal of World-Systems Research ...

Entire Volume 17 issue 1 - Journal of World-Systems Research ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

ECOLOGY, CAPITAL AND THE NATURE OF OUR TIMES 132<br />

possibilities <strong>of</strong> recasting the inner contradictions <strong>of</strong> capital accumulation as dynamic socioecological<br />

forces (Burkett 1999). These possibilities can be realized by treating Marx’s<br />

“progressive tendency” towards a “gradual fall in the general rate <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it” (1981:318-319) as a<br />

historical proposition on the long-run relation between the overproduction <strong>of</strong> machinery and the<br />

underproduction <strong>of</strong> inputs. This illuminates a decisive point <strong>of</strong> fracture in the longue durée <strong>of</strong><br />

historical capitalism, locating biophysical disequilibria within the circuits <strong>of</strong> capital. In so doing,<br />

it provides a basis for a much broader conceptualization <strong>of</strong> cyclical and cumulative crises in the<br />

modern world-ecology than hitherto possible.<br />

Could it be that since the 1830s, capitalism’s technological dynamism has forged agroextractive<br />

complexes capable <strong>of</strong> outrunning the tendency towards the underproduction <strong>of</strong> inputs?<br />

If a sufficient mass <strong>of</strong> cheap energy and raw materials can be mobilized, the rising organic<br />

composition can be attenuated; especially if “capital saving” innovations run strongly alongside<br />

labor saving movements. 22<br />

This not only checks, but (for a time) reverses, the tendency towards a<br />

falling rate <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it.<br />

A similar argument can be made for variable capital (human nature.) If a sufficient<br />

volume <strong>of</strong> cheap food can be supplied to workers the rate <strong>of</strong> surplus value may be augmented in a<br />

manner roughly analogous to wage freezes and technical innovations. The most spectacular<br />

booms in the capitalist era have combined cheap labor and cheap inputs – think <strong>of</strong> English<br />

industrialization with its heavy reliance on cheap energy (coal) and cheap calories (sugar)<br />

(Wrigley 1988; Mintz 1985).<br />

I have argued that underproduction and overproduction are dialectically bound, and that<br />

our investigations ought to focus on their shifting configurations. The late 19 th century’s long<br />

depression <strong>of</strong>fers a promising illustration <strong>of</strong> the possibilities. <strong>World</strong> prices for raw materials<br />

imported by Britain began to rise sharply during the 1860s and ‘70s, at the very moment <strong>of</strong> its<br />

peak industrial supremacy (Hobsbawm 1975; Rostow 1938; Mandel 1975). This inflationary<br />

moment was quickly turned inside-out, as prices in general declined quite sharply (Landes 1969).<br />

At the same time, an inflationary undercurrent was at play. The era was punctuated by successive<br />

(if partial) moments <strong>of</strong> underproduction in such key raw materials sectors as cotton, indigo,<br />

rubber, palm oil, copper, nickel, lead, tin, jute, and sisal (Headrick 1996; Mandel 1975; Brockway<br />

1979; Bukharin 1929; Magd<strong>of</strong>f 1969:30-40). These inflationary undercurrents were set in motion<br />

by the rise <strong>of</strong> new industrial powers, Germany and the United States above all. They were<br />

amplified further still by the qualitative shifts <strong>of</strong> the “second” industrial revolution, premised on<br />

the auto, steel, petrochemical, and electrical industries (Barraclough 167:45-63; Landes 1969).<br />

The underproductionist tendency was consequently checked, but not abolished, by the<br />

second industrial revolution. Ins<strong>of</strong>ar as we restrict our attention to the new industrializers, the<br />

inner contradiction between value accumulation and the production <strong>of</strong> inputs was intensified. The<br />

contradiction was resolved through the dialectic <strong>of</strong> plunder and productivity characteristic <strong>of</strong><br />

capitalism’s successive global ecological fixes: 1) the radical enlargement <strong>of</strong> the geographical<br />

arena, with the rapid acceleration <strong>of</strong> colonial and white settler expansion; and 2) the “massive<br />

penetration <strong>of</strong> capital into the production <strong>of</strong> raw materials,” especially in the newly-incorporated<br />

zones (Mandel 1975:61). There is no question that steam power augmented the capacities <strong>of</strong><br />

capitalist agencies to transform space. A modest amount <strong>of</strong> capital mobilized a relatively vast<br />

22<br />

Between 1980 and 2005, for example, the “relative price <strong>of</strong> capital goods” declined 25-40 percent in the<br />

U.S. and Japan (BIS 2006:24).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!