17.11.2012 Views

Entire Volume 17 issue 1 - Journal of World-Systems Research ...

Entire Volume 17 issue 1 - Journal of World-Systems Research ...

Entire Volume 17 issue 1 - Journal of World-Systems Research ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ECOLOGY, CAPITAL AND THE NATURE OF OUR TIMES 136<br />

Here is a way to engage the popular and scholarly debate over socio-ecological limits<br />

without invoking neo-Malthusian or millenarian notions – a discourse that has recently enjoyed a<br />

renaissance around peak oil and climate change. (This is hardly to deny the evidence for both!)<br />

To be perfectly clear: There are limits. But just what is the best way to identify, to narrate, and to<br />

explain the emergence <strong>of</strong> these limits, historically and in the present conjuncture?<br />

It is not my intention to chart any single “best way,” but rather to argue for the<br />

internalization <strong>of</strong> nature-as-oikeios into the fundamental methodological and conceptual frames <strong>of</strong><br />

world-historical studies. I am doubtful that either the world-systems perspective or Left Ecology<br />

can effectively engage the present global crisis without engaging in a creative dialogue over the<br />

most productive ways to move from red-green theory to red-green histories <strong>of</strong> capitalism that<br />

transcend the Cartesian divide. Now that a metabolic rift has been discovered on the land, Left<br />

Ecology and the world-historical tradition can proceed to transcending its own, deeply-rooted,<br />

“epistemic rifts” (Schneider and McMichael 2010; Moore 2011a).<br />

Arrighi’s conceptualization <strong>of</strong> time and space as active and endogenous moments in the<br />

theory <strong>of</strong> capitalism opens the possibility for such a transition. Arrighi’s world-historical<br />

imagination pivots on the tensions between time and history, space and geography – between the<br />

theory <strong>of</strong> capital and the history <strong>of</strong> capitalism. Incorporating such tensions is crucial to<br />

incorporating nature as not only empirically consequential to, but as relationally constitutive <strong>of</strong>,<br />

modernity’s master processes. Grounding time, space, and power in the theory <strong>of</strong> organizational<br />

revolutions and the accumulation regimes they construct, Arrighi clears a path to integrating<br />

Braudel’s three socio-historical layers <strong>of</strong> capitalism, market exchange, and material life. The<br />

spatio-temporal configurations <strong>of</strong> geopolitics and finance are “only relatively autonomous from<br />

the logics <strong>of</strong> the lower layers and can be understood only in relation to these other logics”<br />

(Arrighi 1994:26). The tension can be resolved – “if that is possible” – only by returning to these<br />

“lower layers <strong>of</strong> market economy and material life with the knowledge and questions brought<br />

back from the journey and into the top layer [<strong>of</strong> capitalism]” (ibid).<br />

Is such an endeavor possible? The possibility <strong>of</strong> integrating Braudel’s capitalism, market<br />

economy, and material life is the premise <strong>of</strong> much work in critical environmental studies, taking<br />

seriously the interplay between political economy and environmental change. The challenge is to<br />

revise without simply adding more. Arrighi is emphatically correct: “[W]e cannot do everything<br />

at once” (1994:25).<br />

My prescription for cutting through this Gordian Knot turns on value theory as eductive<br />

method. By this, I emphasize a method that draws out, and clarifies, the complexities <strong>of</strong> the<br />

oikeios within a relational rather than Cartesian frame. This allows for three ways <strong>of</strong> seeing<br />

modernity as world-ecology. First, capital is “value in motion” deriving from human labor on the<br />

ground and the sale <strong>of</strong> the resulting commodities in a multi-layered world market. This <strong>of</strong>fers a<br />

non-arbitrary way <strong>of</strong> synthesizing earth-moving (necessarily local) with more expansive<br />

repertoires <strong>of</strong> producing nature, incorporating financial transactions, resource legislation,<br />

agricultural science, geopolitical arrangements such as the Westphalia system, and so on. The<br />

inner connections between earth-moving and the rest <strong>of</strong> the world-ecology do not need to be<br />

established in a priori fashion. Rather, they can be allowed to emerge through the analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

oikeios as a “self-forming whole” (McMichael 1990:386). There are many ways to do this. I have<br />

found useful a “tacking” approach, moving between pivotal changes and conflicts at multiple<br />

geographical scales, from the body to forests to factories to financial centers and back again (e.g.<br />

Moore 2000a, 2002b, 2007a).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!