17.06.2013 Views

I Fiance Apicultural

I Fiance Apicultural

I Fiance Apicultural

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

111<br />

nient), and lastly, the inverse of lagged current income (Table 50). This<br />

study also shows that the marginal propensity to save with respect to<br />

expected family income increases by 33 percent when the expected rate<br />

of return is included.<br />

In Ong's 1972 study of Taiwan, the expected rate of return variable,<br />

among others, is included, and expected income is the most important<br />

variable (Table 51). In the Republic of Korea (1-lyun, Adams, and [-lshak<br />

1979), pernanent income is the most important variable, while transitory<br />

income is the least important (Table 52). Even this study shows that the<br />

marginal propensity to save is sensitive to the exclusion of the expected<br />

rate of return to capital ,san explanatory variable. Among other variables<br />

that are more important than incentives to save are interaction of pemlanent<br />

income with (1) the dependency ratio in the family, (2) the value of<br />

liquid asscis, and (3) cultivated land. But, when rural saving is defined per<br />

household inmtead of per capita, then interaction of peritanent income<br />

with th e At retunli to capital is the second most important factor. In<br />

Gupta's (19701)) study on rural household saving in India, transitory<br />

income is the n ost important variable, followed by riilaen<br />

t<br />

and<br />

income,<br />

then tle treal rate of interest oh treasti-y bills (Table 50). Among the<br />

remain ing six studies oil ecot lotl ly-widc saving,<br />

i the mlajority show that<br />

incentive to save is the least important variable. 'Tiis is also the- case with<br />

gross national saving ill the Republic of Korea. lit tie United States,<br />

incentives to save are broadly more significant thtan some of the measures<br />

of ability to save, though the latter, with its tItore direct measurement, is<br />

more important than the real rate of rett!!n to capital (Boskin 1978) (Table<br />

53). In conclusion, in all the cottrics under reference, ability to save is<br />

more important than incentives to save.<br />

Response of Rural Saving<br />

to the Interest Rate<br />

As mentioned earlier in the context of total saving, the interest<br />

deposits<br />

rate on<br />

is a proxy for the rate of rcturn to capital because of the<br />

difficulty of measuring the true detertinant. Despite this difficulty,<br />

determinant<br />

this<br />

has been studied in three papers on rural saving (B.M.<br />

Desai 1975; l-Iyin, Adams, and 1-Hushak 1979; and Ong 1972) and one<br />

ott economy-wide private-sector saving (Boskin 1978). Irrespective of the<br />

nature of thte measurement of the variable ott incentive to save, it is not<br />

possible to guess whether its impact on saving will be positive<br />

(B.<br />

or negative<br />

M. Desai 1983b; Miksell and Zinscr 1973; Snyder 197,1). Nor can the<br />

magnitude of its elasticity he hypothesized because, wletn the variable<br />

for incentive to Save improves, two types of'effects result: ou is a pure<br />

substitution effect aitd the other is all incotC effect. TIhe substitution<br />

effect is always positive because savers wil substitute ftture consuttliption<br />

for )resent consunnptionl, and consequently they will save<br />

when<br />

more<br />

the expected rate of rethrn increases. The income effect is indeterminate,<br />

as'shown in B. M. I)esai 19831). It can be negative or positive.<br />

When the present value of net income increases after a rise in<br />

interest<br />

the<br />

rate or the rate of return, savers will decrease saving and

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!