20.01.2015 Views

Debt: The First 5000 Years - autonomous learning

Debt: The First 5000 Years - autonomous learning

Debt: The First 5000 Years - autonomous learning

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

10 8 DEBT<br />

developed where local bankers would lend money to such VISitors to<br />

finance particularly spectacular gifts, knowing they could be well repaid<br />

from the proceeds of royal one-upmanship. <strong>The</strong> king must have<br />

known about this. He didn't object-since the whole point was to<br />

show that his wealth exceeded all possible equivalence-and if he really<br />

needed to, he could always expropriate the bankers. <strong>The</strong>y knew<br />

that the really important game was not economic, but one of status,<br />

and his was absolute.<br />

In exchange, the objects being traded are seen as equivalent. <strong>The</strong>refore,<br />

by implication, so are the people: at least, at the moment when<br />

gift is met with counter-gift, or money changes hands; when there is<br />

no further debt or obligation and each of the two parties is equally<br />

free to walk away. This in turn implies autonomy. Both principles sit<br />

uncomfortably with monarchs, which is the reason that kings generally<br />

dislike any sort of exchange.34 But within that overhanging prospect of<br />

potential cancellation, of ultimate equivalence, we find endless variations,<br />

endless games one can play. One can demand something from<br />

another person, knowing that by doing so, one is giving the other the<br />

right to demand something of equivalent value in return. In some contexts,<br />

even praising another's possession might be interpreted as a demand<br />

of this sort. In eighteenth-century New Zealand, English settlers<br />

soon learned that it was not a good idea to admire, say, a particularly<br />

beautiful jade pendant worn around the neck of a Maori warrior; the<br />

latter would inevitably insist on giving it, not take no for an answer,<br />

and then, after a discreet interval, return to praise the settler's coat<br />

or gun. <strong>The</strong> only way to head this off was to quickly give him a gift<br />

before he could ask for one. Sometimes gifts are offered in order for<br />

the giver to be able to make such a demand: if one accepts the present,<br />

one is tacitly agreeing to allow the giver to claim whatever he deems<br />

equivalent.35<br />

All this, in turn, can shade into something very much like barter,<br />

directly swapping one thing for another-which as we've seen does<br />

occur even in what Marcel Mauss liked to refer to as "gift economies,"<br />

even if largely between strangers.16 Within communities, there<br />

is almost always a reluctance, as the Tiv example so nicely illustrates,<br />

to allow things to cancel out-one reason that if there is money in<br />

common usage, people will often either refuse to use it with friends or<br />

relatives (which in a village society includes pretty much everyone), or<br />

alternately, like the Malagasy villagers in chapter 3, use it in radically<br />

different ways.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!