20.01.2015 Views

Debt: The First 5000 Years - autonomous learning

Debt: The First 5000 Years - autonomous learning

Debt: The First 5000 Years - autonomous learning

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

THE MIDDLE AGES 275<br />

since the dawn of recorded history. Finally, Islam strictly forbade usury,<br />

which it interpreted to mean any arrangement in which money<br />

or a commodity was lent at interest, for any purpose whatsoever.68<br />

In a way, one can see the establishment of Islamic courts as the<br />

ultimate triumph of the patriarchal rebellion that had begun so many<br />

thousands of years before: of the ethos of the desert or the steppe,<br />

real or imagined, even as the faithful did their best to keep the heavily<br />

armed descendants of actual nomads confined to their camps and palaces.<br />

It was made possible by a profound shift in class alliances. <strong>The</strong><br />

great urban civilizations of the Middle East had always been dominated<br />

by a de facto alliance between administrators and merchants, both<br />

of whom kept the rest of the population either in debt peonage or in<br />

constant peril of falling into it. In converting to Islam, the commercial<br />

classes, so long the arch-villains in the eyes of ordinary farmers and<br />

townsfolk, effectively agreed to change sides, abandon all their most<br />

hated practices, and become instead the leaders of a society that now<br />

defined itself against the state.<br />

It was possible because from the beginning, Islam had a positive<br />

view toward commerce. Mohammed himself had begun his adult life as<br />

a merchant; and no Islamic thinker ever treated the honest pursuit of<br />

profit as itself intrinsically immoral or inimical to faith. Neither did the<br />

prohibitions against usury-which for the most part were scrupulously<br />

enforced, even in the case of commercial loans-in any sense mitigate<br />

against the growth of commerce, or even the development of complex<br />

credit instruments.69 To the contrary, the early centuries of the Caliphate<br />

saw an immediate efflorescence in both.<br />

Profits were still possible because Islamic jurists were careful to<br />

allow for certain service fees, and other considerations-notably, allowing<br />

goods bought on credit to be priced slightly higher than those<br />

bought for cash-that ensured that bankers and traders still had an<br />

incentive to provide credit services.70 Still, these incentives were never<br />

enough to allow banking to become a full-time occupation: instead,<br />

almost any merchant operating on a sufficiently large scale could be<br />

expected to combine banking with a host of other moneymaking activities.<br />

As a result, credit instruments soon became so essential to trade<br />

that almost anyone of prominence was expected to keep most of his<br />

or her wealth on deposit, and to make everyday transactions, not by<br />

counting out coins, but by inkpot and paper. Promissory notes were<br />

called sakk, "checks", or ruq' a, "notes." Checks could bounce. One<br />

German historian, picking through a multitude of old Arabic literary<br />

sources, recounts that:

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!