20.01.2015 Views

Debt: The First 5000 Years - autonomous learning

Debt: The First 5000 Years - autonomous learning

Debt: The First 5000 Years - autonomous learning

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

114 DEBT<br />

friends, and feudal lords when dealing with small children . It is very<br />

hard to imagine a society where people wouldn't be both.<br />

<strong>The</strong> obvious question is: If we are all ordinarily moving back and<br />

forth between completely different systems of moral accounting, why<br />

hasn't anybody noticed this Why, instead, do we continually feel the<br />

need to reframe everything in terms of reciprocity<br />

Here we must return to the fact that reciprocity is our main way of<br />

imagining justice. In particular, it is what we fall back on when we're<br />

thinking in the abstract, and especially when we're trying to create an<br />

idealized picture of society. I've already given examples of this sort of<br />

thing. Iroquois communities were based on an ethos that required everyone<br />

to be attentive to the needs of several different sorts of people:<br />

their friends, their families, members of their matrilineal clans, even<br />

friendly strangers in situations of hardship. It was when they had to<br />

think about society in the abstract that they started to emphasize the<br />

two sides of the village, each of which had to bury the other's dead.<br />

It was a way of imagining communism through reciprocity. Similarly,<br />

feudalism was a notoriously messy and complicated business, but whenever<br />

Medieval thinkers generalized about it, they reduced all its ranks<br />

and orders into one simple formula in which each order contributed its<br />

share: "Some pray, some fight, still others work. "45 Even hierarchy was<br />

seen as ultimately reciprocal, despite this formula having nothing to<br />

do with the real relations between priests, knights, and peasants really<br />

operated on the ground. Anthropologists are familiar with the phenomenon:<br />

it's only when people who have never had occasion to really<br />

think about their society or culture as a whole, who probably weren't<br />

even aware they were living inside something other people considered<br />

a "society" or a "culture," are asked to explain how everything works<br />

that they say things like "this is how we repay our mothers for the pain<br />

of having raised us," or puzzle over conceptual diagrams in which clan<br />

A gives their women in marriage to clan B who gives theirs to clan C,<br />

who gives theirs back to A again, but which never seem to quite correspond<br />

to what real people actually do.46 When trying to imagine a<br />

just society, it's hard not to evoke images of balance and symmetry, of<br />

elegant geometries where everything balances out.<br />

<strong>The</strong> idea that there is something called "the market" is not so very<br />

different. Economists will often admit this, if you ask them in the right<br />

way. Markets aren't real. <strong>The</strong>y are mathematical models, created by<br />

imagining a self-contained world where everyone has exactly the same<br />

motivation and the same knowledge and is engaging in the same selfinterested<br />

calculating exchange. Economists are aware that reality is<br />

always more complicated; but they are also aware that to come up with

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!