12.07.2015 Views

The Challenge of Low-Carbon Development - World Bank Internet ...

The Challenge of Low-Carbon Development - World Bank Internet ...

The Challenge of Low-Carbon Development - World Bank Internet ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>of</strong> the Kyoto Protocol, is supposed to reduce the cost <strong>of</strong>achieving that goal, making it easier for countries to agreeon what to do and how to pay for it. It does this by requiringdeveloped countries to limit their emissions, but allowingthem to meet that limit by paying to reduce emissions (buyingcarbon credits) abroad rather than at home. Developingcountries face no caps but can sell carbon <strong>of</strong>fsets—reductions<strong>of</strong> emissions compared with emission levels from doingbusiness as usual.<strong>The</strong>re are cheaper opportunities to reduceemissions in transition and developingcountries than in developed ones.<strong>The</strong> carbon market, inspired by successful market-basedschemes to reduce acid rain, was attractive for several reasons.<strong>The</strong> atmosphere does not care where the CO 2comesfrom—the impact on climate change is the same. Comparedwith developed countries, transition and developing countrieshave cheaper opportunities to reduce emissions, theformer through replacing a legacy <strong>of</strong> energy-wasting infrastructureand industry and the latter by installing efficientnew equipment to meet rapidly growing energy demands.<strong>The</strong> carbon market can provide money and technology fordeveloping country infrastructure. Because carbon creditsare a priced commodity, developing countries can realizepr<strong>of</strong>its if they can produce them cheaply. Having a price oncarbon emissions may motivate research and developmentfor low-carbon technologies. Finally, some view the carbonmarket as a more reliable means <strong>of</strong> raising funds from developedcountries (which are historically responsible forcurrent levels <strong>of</strong> GHGs) than the competing alternative: directannual appropriations from those countries’ individualnational budgets.In contrast, the carbon market faces significant practicalobstacles. <strong>The</strong> logic <strong>of</strong> the system requires that emissionsreductions must represent a new, additional effort so thatthe developed country’s extra emissions are exactly <strong>of</strong>fsetby reductions elsewhere. Otherwise, buyers and sellersmight collude and claim bogus carbon credits, and totalemissions would increase. To prevent this, an elaborateproject-by-project validation system has been set up underthe auspices <strong>of</strong> the CDM to certify the additionality <strong>of</strong> carboncredits (box 5.2).Box 5.2<strong>Carbon</strong> Offsets—A Peculiar Commodity<strong>Carbon</strong> <strong>of</strong>fsets are a peculiar commodity. <strong>The</strong>y are defined as the difference between the number <strong>of</strong> tons <strong>of</strong> GHGyou emit and the number <strong>of</strong> tons you would have emitted had you not been paid not to emit them. In an idealizedexample, the <strong>of</strong>fer <strong>of</strong> carbon payments might induce a utility to build a geothermal power plant (with no emissions)rather than a cheaper diesel plant (which would have emitted 100,000 tons per year). <strong>The</strong> <strong>of</strong>fset would thenbe 100,000 tons per year.Actual emissions can be measured with instruments, but quantifying counterfactual, business-as-usual emissionsis difficult. Both sellers and buyers have an incentive to claim <strong>of</strong>fsets for a project that they were going to doanyway—projects that are not “additional.” But if many people did this, then these bogus <strong>of</strong>fsets would be used bypurchasers to increase their emissions above agreed limits, frustrating the goal <strong>of</strong> the Kyoto Protocol.This is the heart <strong>of</strong> the additionality dilemma. <strong>The</strong> CDM has set up an elaborate system for determining additionalityfor each proposed project. <strong>The</strong> project proponent must argue that carbon funding is critical to project bankabilityor helps to overcome other kinds <strong>of</strong> barriers. Methodologies for demonstrating additionality are developedat some cost by the first people to undertake a specific kind <strong>of</strong> project. <strong>The</strong>n, if approved by the CDM, that methodologyis available to others, accelerating project approval. <strong>The</strong> CDM uses private third-party verifiers to validateadditionality claims and to verify annual reports <strong>of</strong> emissions reductions.In sum, the carbon <strong>of</strong>fset commodity is in effect an impact evaluation, and an elaborate institutional mechanismhas been set up to conduct that evaluation. Few other development projects attract the same degree <strong>of</strong> scrutinyon impacts.However, the additionality screening process has been widely criticized as ponderous, costly, and ineffective.Environmentalists press for stricter screening, investors for more streamlined procedures. <strong>The</strong> current system maycombine the worst <strong>of</strong> both worlds: high transaction cost with substantial nonadditionality. A growing consensusviews determination <strong>of</strong> additionality as quixotic at the project level. An alternative would be to set up technologyspecificcrediting rules, creating a system akin to a feed-in tariff premium for renewable energy or energy efficiency,with higher credits for less-competitive technologies.Source: IEG.72 | Climate Change and the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Group

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!