12.07.2015 Views

Download the Indonesia Human Development Report 2004. - UNDP

Download the Indonesia Human Development Report 2004. - UNDP

Download the Indonesia Human Development Report 2004. - UNDP

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

nets that could automatically be activated in an economicdownturn – an additional argument for having suchprogrammes in <strong>the</strong> future.It should be emphasized, however, that simplyincreasing social spending will not in itself improve socialservices. In <strong>the</strong> past public spending has often been oflow quality, compromised by widespread corruption andrent-seeking – though this inefficiency and <strong>the</strong> consequentdrain on public resources was masked by economicgrowth and by oil revenues that sustained public finances.In <strong>the</strong> current, more constrained environment <strong>the</strong>government will have to pay much more attention towastage and cost effectiveness.It will also have to tackle corruption. Evidence fromcross-country comparisons suggests that corruption notonly reduces efficiency it also alters <strong>the</strong> composition ofgovernment spending – tending to reduced education andhealth investment, presumably because compared witho<strong>the</strong>r areas <strong>the</strong>se expenditures offer fewer opportunitiesfor rent-seeking. 71 Fortunately in a more open anddemocratic environment fiscal policymaking can besubjected to greater scrutiny and <strong>the</strong> rigours of democraticdebate and can also be tailored to <strong>the</strong> new realities ofdecentralization.Social spending under fiscal decentralizationFollowing decentralization from 2001, <strong>Indonesia</strong> hasnow experienced nearly three years of regional autonomythat has shifted much of <strong>the</strong> responsibility for publicservices to <strong>the</strong> local level. And whereas in <strong>the</strong> past flowsof funds from <strong>the</strong> centre to <strong>the</strong> regions generally took <strong>the</strong>form of earmarked grants <strong>the</strong> new fiscal framework relieslargely on a general grant. Along side fiscal decentralization,<strong>the</strong> country has switched to a new accountability systemat <strong>the</strong> local level, with <strong>the</strong> head of <strong>the</strong> region being electedby regional parliaments, which in turn are elected bypopular vote.This new system entails certain risks but <strong>the</strong>se shouldbe outweighed by <strong>the</strong> benefits. In place of <strong>the</strong> earlier topdowntechnocratic approach to resource allocation, <strong>the</strong>new system allows available resources to be bettermatched to local needs. Chapter two of this report hasdemonstrated that regions differ not just in <strong>the</strong>ir overalllevels of human development but also in <strong>the</strong>ir patterns ofdeficiency in <strong>the</strong> different dimensions of humandevelopment. Each region will thus have its own priorities.In education, for example, some regions have an excellentrecord in primary enrolment, but have done ra<strong>the</strong>r poorlyin junior secondary enrolment. 72The new system fosters a rights-based approach tohuman development since it should allow local people toparticipate in decision making on resource allocation andprogramme implementation. This is not just a democraticimperative, it also has economic benefits. The differentareas of human development and poverty alleviation havesynergistic relationships –interventions in one can reinforce<strong>the</strong> impact of ano<strong>the</strong>r (Box 3.3, p. 28). For example, if<strong>the</strong> aim is to increase school enrolment, investment inbuilding more schools will be much more effective if it isaccompanied by efforts to reduce <strong>the</strong> extreme povertythat often keeps children away from school. However, itis difficult for planners to devise a combination ofinterventions based simply on economic criteria. Localpeople, with superior information about <strong>the</strong> complexitiesof local needs are in a better position to achieve this balance.Local governments can also be more flexible andresponsive when it comes to budgeting. When drawingup budgets, central planners tend to replicate previouspatterns of expenditure, making incremental adjustments.At <strong>the</strong> local level, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong>re should be muchgreater scope for a fresh approach – starting again fromscratch with what is called ‘zero-based’ budgeting (seeBox 5.1). When <strong>the</strong> aim is to make a distinct break with<strong>the</strong> past this approach helps reorient public spending muchmore towards human development.Decentralization does, of course, also entail risks. Thereis no guarantee that opportunities for local level flexibilitywill be used in a positive way. While some regions arealready forging ahead with innovations in service delivery,o<strong>the</strong>rs have allocated only meagre amounts to health andeducation. One way to address this is by establishingminimum service delivery standards. However, <strong>the</strong>sestandards will need to be supported financially – throughequalizing grants from <strong>the</strong> central government to <strong>the</strong>poorest districts.Ano<strong>the</strong>r danger of decentralization is that corruptionand rent-seeking at <strong>the</strong> centre will be replicated, in aneven worse form, at <strong>the</strong> local level – again not only wastingresources but also jeopardizing <strong>the</strong> prospect of betterresource allocations. Corrupt local governments may, forexample, show a bias towards large construction projectson which it is easier to collect substantial bribes, ra<strong>the</strong>rthan towards routine expenditure such as textbook supplyor teachers’ salaries. The spending priorities can thuseasily get distorted.Decentralization also requires stronger local institutions.People’s needs can be reflected in resource allocationsonly if <strong>the</strong>re are institutional mechanisms that canarticulate such needs. Local people will need to worktoge<strong>the</strong>r in community-based organizations through which<strong>the</strong>y, and not just local elites, can have a say overallocations. They can also better identify impact ofmisgovernance and corruption – whe<strong>the</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> poor qualityof schooling or health care or in <strong>the</strong> weak implementationof local development projects. They are <strong>the</strong>refore in abetter position to make well informed criticisms anddemand better governance.71 See Mauro (2002).72 For example, Bangkalan district in East Java has a high primary enrolment ratio of 98%, but its junior school enrolment rate is only about 40%, compared to <strong>the</strong> district averageof about 70%. The situation is similar in Pandeglang in West Java.54National <strong>Human</strong> <strong>Development</strong> <strong>Report</strong> 2004

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!