12.07.2015 Views

Download the Indonesia Human Development Report 2004. - UNDP

Download the Indonesia Human Development Report 2004. - UNDP

Download the Indonesia Human Development Report 2004. - UNDP

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Ano<strong>the</strong>r risk from decentralization is that it couldexacerbate regional disparities. <strong>Indonesia</strong> already has sharpcontrasts between districts: in 2001, on a per capita basis<strong>the</strong> richest local government had 50 times more revenuethan <strong>the</strong> poorest one. 73 These gaps seem likely to widen.This is first because districts are now allowed to keep ashare of <strong>the</strong> benefits from oil and o<strong>the</strong>r natural resourcesthat are on <strong>the</strong>ir territories. Second <strong>the</strong> richer districtshave a stronger tax base so should be able to gain morerevenue from local taxes. As a result, while <strong>the</strong> richerregions should have more resources to invest in humandevelopment <strong>the</strong> poorer regions will be hard-pressed toattain minimum service standards, let alone improve upon<strong>the</strong>m. As <strong>the</strong> regions get more taxing authority, this willneed to be offset by equalizing arrangements for revenuesharing.Never<strong>the</strong>less, it seems inevitable that regional disparitieswill remain for <strong>the</strong> foreseeable future and that someregions will prosper more than o<strong>the</strong>rs. In <strong>the</strong>secircumstances <strong>Indonesia</strong> needs to arrive at a nationalconsensus on meeting citizens’ human development rightsand should establish a minimum socially acceptableuniversal level of human development and allocate itsresources accordingly.This does not necessarily mean aiming for equality ofincome but ra<strong>the</strong>r for equity in <strong>the</strong> development of humancapabilities. This not only fulfils people’s basic rights, italso brings economic benefits since public investment inhuman development is likely to bring higher returns inrelatively backward regions than in <strong>the</strong> advanced regions.For example, new schools are likely to attract more newstudents in areas where enrolment is relatively low. 74 Thismay also be true of many small-scale investment projects,such as those for irrigation, where investment can creategreater income-earning opportunities for <strong>the</strong> poor than if<strong>the</strong>y were invested in large-scale manufacturing or serviceindustries.A social sector fund – a means to protect socialspendingHow can <strong>the</strong> government ensure that social spendingis raised and maintained given tight budgetary constraintsand <strong>the</strong> implications of decentralization? One way todemonstrate <strong>the</strong> government’s commitment is to earmarkfunds for designated social spending by creating a SocialSector Fund (SSF). 75There are a number of ways a SSF can be created.For example, it could be built up by taking a certainpercentage of proceeds from <strong>the</strong> exploitation of naturalresources. Since <strong>the</strong>se resources are ultimately ownedby all <strong>Indonesia</strong>ns one of <strong>the</strong> best ways to ensure that <strong>the</strong>benefits are shared equitably is through social spending.Regions with richer resource endowments would thusmake a larger contribution.As <strong>the</strong> <strong>Indonesia</strong>n economy becomes more marketcentred, fewer public funds will be needed to subsidizestate-owned enterprises, leaving resources that can beredirected to <strong>the</strong> social sector. Moreover, following <strong>the</strong>example of <strong>the</strong> fuel subsidy compensation fund, 76 <strong>the</strong> SSFcould also be allocated a percentage of <strong>the</strong> proceeds fromprivatization and from any savings from reforms andrestructuring. India, for example, uses this system and in2001-02 allocated <strong>the</strong> equivalent of Rp. 1 billion fromprivatization proceeds to <strong>the</strong> social sectors. 77 This systemhas <strong>the</strong> added advantage of creating greater support forreforms. 78Ano<strong>the</strong>r possibility is to apply a social sector levy oncorporations. This can be justified to corporations on <strong>the</strong>grounds that it can help moderate wage claims: workerswho as a result of greater social spending benefit fromsubsidised or free education, health care and o<strong>the</strong>r socialservices should have less need to press for higher wages.A social fund levy would not <strong>the</strong>refore necessarily add tobusiness costs. Businesses also gain since <strong>the</strong>y can takeadvantage of a better educated and better nourished labourforce that will be more productive. 79 A similar levy can beapplied to wealthy individuals. This could also be linkedto Zakat – an obligatory charity for well-to-do Muslims –allowing <strong>the</strong> SSF levy to be offset against Zakat. Thesemandatory funding sources of SSF can also besupplemented by voluntary contributions through taxdeductible charities and donations.However, this kind of system can only work ifcontributors to <strong>the</strong> fund, whe<strong>the</strong>r compulsory orvoluntary, have confidence in its management. Peoplegenerally comply with such revenue collecting measureswhen <strong>the</strong>y see <strong>the</strong>ir money is spent on worthy causes.73 See World Bank (2003a), p.iv.74 To some extent, this may be counterbalanced by <strong>the</strong> higher costs of providing services in remote areas.75 One may argue that such earmarked funds are fungible. That is, overall spending does not necessarily increase in <strong>the</strong> earmarked sector, as <strong>the</strong> government shifts its non-earmarkedspending to o<strong>the</strong>r sectors. However, <strong>the</strong>re is very little evidence for this. Most empirical studies find that when funds are earmarked, spending does increase, although it maynot rise by <strong>the</strong> expected amount.76 In <strong>the</strong> 1999/2000 budget fuel subsidies amounted to Rp. 40.9 trillion. In <strong>the</strong> 2001 budget, Rp. 2.2 trillion were allocated to a social compensation fund for education, health,food, transportation, clean water etc. In <strong>the</strong> 2002 budget <strong>the</strong> allocation was Rp. 2.85 trillion, including Rp. 570 billion for <strong>the</strong> health sector to cover free in-patient care for <strong>the</strong>poor in 446 public hospitals, free generic drugs for 47.9 million poor and free hepatitis vaccines for 1.5 million poor people. In 2003, Rp. 4.43 trillion were budgeted tocompensate 30 million people for <strong>the</strong> effects of <strong>the</strong> 22% increase in fuel prices.77 Prabhu (2003).78 The Australian government successfully generated support for <strong>the</strong> sale of publicly owned telecommunication corporation, Telstra, by creating a special fund from <strong>the</strong> salesproceeds to be used for <strong>the</strong> environmental cause.79 Singapore successfully used a levy on corporations to create a Skill <strong>Development</strong> Fund (SDF) for financing <strong>the</strong> training of unskilled workers. This eventually raisedproductivity and hence reduced unit labour costs which helped corporations to enhance and maintain <strong>the</strong>ir international competitiveness. Ano<strong>the</strong>r example of a successfulearmarked levy is <strong>the</strong> Employment Guarantee Scheme in <strong>the</strong> state of Maharashtra in India which is funded through resources raised mainly from urban areas to provideemployment for unskilled labour in rural areas.National <strong>Human</strong> <strong>Development</strong> <strong>Report</strong> 2004 55

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!