26.03.2013 Views

Appendix CASE ONE - Collection Point® | The Total Digital Asset ...

Appendix CASE ONE - Collection Point® | The Total Digital Asset ...

Appendix CASE ONE - Collection Point® | The Total Digital Asset ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Chapter 9<br />

Default and Modem Process<br />

Stephen C. Yeazell<br />

Medieval and early modern English law lacked a procedural mechanism<br />

that modern legal process takes for granted: the default judgement. 1 Until<br />

1725 a plaintiff could not secure a judgement in a personal action unless<br />

the defendant chose to appear in court and answer the charges. Only by<br />

the enactment of 12 George I c. 29 did it become possible to secure the<br />

entry of such a judgement in a personal action against a defendant who,<br />

properly summoned, nevertheless failed to appear. To untutored modern<br />

eyes the absence until modern times of a default mechanism seems puzzling.<br />

In modern English and American procedure the threat of a default judgement<br />

is the quiet hinge on which much adversarial process turns. Default compels<br />

the defendant to answer and keeps him in the game after it has started.<br />

Default enables modern process to place enormous burdens on adversarial<br />

shoulders in the confidence that they will not simply shrug them off. We think<br />

of medieval and early modern process as adversarial to a fault, yet it lacked<br />

this mechanism we regard as basic. <strong>The</strong> emergence of a default mechanism in<br />

eighteenth century England raises a question that can take two forms. One can<br />

ask why default emerged so late: how could medieval process function without<br />

a mechanism that seems to moderns so central? Alternatively, one can ask<br />

why default emerged at all: if English law functioned adequately without<br />

default for five hundred years, what changed? Both forms of the question<br />

yield insights into the development of a modern conception of legal process<br />

in early modern times.<br />

Medieval law could function without default in personal actions because<br />

it did have default in real actions and because it had a variety of devices<br />

that compelled defendants to appear and answer in personal actions. Each<br />

of these devices yielded fees to the officials who administered them. One<br />

can understand the late adoption of default in personal actions as a tribute<br />

to the success of these compensating mechanisms, to the late development of a<br />

sharp distinction between civil and criminal processes, and to the hardiness of<br />

belief that office-holders held property in their fees. As wealth began to move<br />

from land to intangibles, personal actions (which dealt with such intangibles)<br />

1 I am grateful for the thoughtful comments of Paul Brand, Kenneth Graham, William<br />

McGovern, Mark Ramseyer, David Seipp and John S. Wiley.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!