26.03.2013 Views

Appendix CASE ONE - Collection Point® | The Total Digital Asset ...

Appendix CASE ONE - Collection Point® | The Total Digital Asset ...

Appendix CASE ONE - Collection Point® | The Total Digital Asset ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Default and Modern Process 135<br />

seems to be the importance of having a system of easily transferable ownership<br />

and of efficient enforcement. Default judgements contribute to the latter goal.<br />

Straightforward though the argument is, the economic evidence will support<br />

it only in a limited form. In spite of the notorious South Sea Bubble,<br />

ownership of private shares was not a widespread form of seventeenth- or<br />

eighteenth-century wealth holding. <strong>The</strong> financial revolution of the eighteenth<br />

century came in public, not in private finance. 31 True, the Bank of England<br />

regularized national credit and enabled Britain to conduct several expensive<br />

wars without jeopardizing internal security. Its shares became a standard form<br />

of investment among the small class fortunate enough to have money to invest.<br />

But the important thing about the Bank was that it did pay its debts; it never<br />

tested the efficacy of legal enforcement mechanisms. Even if it had, one can<br />

scarcely imagine that the availability of default judgements would have swayed<br />

a prospective creditor of the Bank. If the Bank had failed, high politics, not<br />

creditors' remedies, would have determined the outcome.<br />

Private credit was another matter, one more amenable to explanation in<br />

terms of the North-Thomas thesis. A wide network of small credit covered<br />

seventeenth-century Britain, made essential in part by the chronic shortage<br />

of currency: 32<br />

Although the demand for credit was great, the market for credit was disorganized,<br />

particularly for long-term loans. Lenders were a motley collection, frequently<br />

indistinguishable as a group, for money-lending was a spare-time occupation for<br />

most people . . . farmers, shopkeepers, petty traders . . . merchants. . . widows.<br />

Such a situation sounds like the stuff to bolster the North-Thomas argument<br />

in a carefully limited form. Petty credit in the aggregate can be important<br />

to a national economy, and default judgements would have significance<br />

in speeding the flow of petty debt collection: such debtors are the least<br />

likely to raise defences and such creditors are most likely to see a<br />

connection between legal remedies and debt collection. We have good<br />

evidence that such creditors made heavy use of the legal system. As<br />

C.W. Brooks' study of the lower branches of the bar argues, <strong>The</strong> single<br />

most important fact about the history of the profession (and the system<br />

within which it operated) during this period is that from the mid sixteenth<br />

century until the outbreak of the Civil War, litigation came flooding into<br />

Westminster Hall both suddenly and on an unprecedented scale'. 33 Actions<br />

of debt dominated this increase. In both King's Bench and Common Pleas,<br />

roughly 80 per cent of the seventeenth-century actions filed employed the<br />

writ of debt, a significant increase over the previous century. 34 Not all<br />

31 P.G.M. Dickson, op. cit. n.28, 489.<br />

32 L.A. Clarkson, op. cit. n.29, 48.<br />

33 C.W. Brooks, op. cit. n.12, 48.<br />

34 Ibid., 69. <strong>The</strong> proportion of debt actions in the total docket increased from 19 per cent (King's<br />

Bench) and 67 per cent (Common Pleas) in 1560 to 80 per cent (King's Bench) and 88 per cent (Common<br />

Pleas) in 1640. Ibid.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!