15.05.2014 Views

The Palestinian Economy. Theoretical and Practical Challenges

The Palestinian Economy. Theoretical and Practical Challenges

The Palestinian Economy. Theoretical and Practical Challenges

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

372<br />

Abu-Zaineh – Mataria<br />

in behaviour across SES groups (called I B ) – i.e., the variation in the parameter estimates<br />

across income groups. <strong>The</strong> findings on the heterogeneity in behaviour for a given need are<br />

also decomposed by parts of the dem<strong>and</strong> process; i.e. for the probability of participation<br />

(called I PP ) <strong>and</strong> the conditional number of usage (called I CC ).<br />

As shown in Table 4.1, with the exception of primary-level, the estimated values of<br />

the concentration index (C y ) of the overall income related-inequality in the utilisation of<br />

each level of health care in the two regions are significantly positive [C y > 0 at p < 0.05].<br />

This indicates that the utilisation of primary-care is generally concentrated among the<br />

poor [C y = –0.0527 <strong>and</strong> –0.0415 for the WB <strong>and</strong> GS, respectively], whereas the utilisation<br />

of secondary-level – both outpatient <strong>and</strong> inpatient services – <strong>and</strong> tertiary-level are<br />

concentrated amongst the better-off, with the C y index being more pro-rich in the case of<br />

secondary-inpatient [C y = 0.0617 <strong>and</strong> 0.0313 for the WB <strong>and</strong> GS, respectively] compared<br />

to secondary-outpatient case [C y = 0.0511 <strong>and</strong> 0.0247 for the WB <strong>and</strong> GS respectively],<br />

while they appear to be even a lot more pronounced in the case of tertiary-care [C y =<br />

0.1311 <strong>and</strong> 0.1204] compared with both types of secondary-care.<br />

<strong>The</strong> estimated values of Need index (the I N ) – i.e., the aggregation or the combined<br />

effects of all morbidity <strong>and</strong> demographic variables included in the model – emerge, on the<br />

other h<strong>and</strong>, invariably significantly negative [I N < 0 at p < 0.05] for all levels of care. This<br />

clearly means that need for health care are always concentrated in the lowest-part of<br />

income distribution, <strong>and</strong> that the poor are, in general, in a poorer health status than the<br />

rich. Indeed, the (partial) contribution of heterogeneity in need (by income) to the<br />

measured degree of inequality in utilisation is captured, as in the previous research (e.g.,<br />

van Doorslaer, Koolman et al. 2004), by adjusting the distribution of utilisation for a set<br />

of morbidity <strong>and</strong> demographic variables (age <strong>and</strong> sex).<br />

However, as shown in Table 4.2, the values of Need Index (I N ) not due to<br />

demographics –i.e., the degree of “need-expected” inequality estimated by allowing for<br />

morbidity differences, while keeping the distribution st<strong>and</strong>ardised for demographic<br />

differences– account for the bulk of the I N value [circa 90% of the I N index value]. <strong>The</strong><br />

partial contributions of age-sex differences to the I N , although push the distribution of<br />

need further in a pro-poor direction, remain comparatively small <strong>and</strong> account for only<br />

10% of the I N index value. This indicates that, although demographic differences play<br />

some role in shaping need for health care, the overall value of our I N is mainly accounted<br />

for by the distribution of morbidity across income, which is significantly more prevalent<br />

amongst the poor.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!