22.07.2013 Views

I Chose Liberty - Ludwig von Mises Institute

I Chose Liberty - Ludwig von Mises Institute

I Chose Liberty - Ludwig von Mises Institute

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

George Reisman 281<br />

positions that I did not want to support, and that I was repeatedly being driven into supporting<br />

such positions.<br />

Neither of the evenings were very pleasant. At one point—I don’t know how we got<br />

to the subject, nor whether it occurred at our first or second meeting—I expressed the<br />

conviction that a void must exist. Otherwise, I did not see how the existence of motion was<br />

possible, since two objects could not occupy the same place at the same time. Ayn Rand’s<br />

reply to my expression of my conviction was that “it was worse than anything a communist<br />

could have said.” (In retrospect, recognizing that the starting point of her philosophy is<br />

that “existence exists,” I realize she took my statement to mean that I upheld the existence<br />

of “nonexistence” and was thus maintaining the worst possible contradiction.)<br />

Because of such unpleasantness, I did not desire to see her again until after I read Atlas<br />

Shrugged. However, I could not forget our meetings and could not help wondering if somehow<br />

she might be right that values really were objective after all. I was very troubled by the<br />

implications of the proposition that all values are ultimately arbitrary and subjective, as<br />

<strong>Mises</strong> claimed. It no longer seemed enough that the great majority of people happened to<br />

prefer life to death, and health and wealth to sickness and poverty. For if they happened<br />

not to, there would be nothing to say to them that could change their minds, and if there<br />

were enough of them, no way to fight them, and, worst of all, no way even morally to<br />

condemn any slaughters they might commit, because if all values really were arbitrary and<br />

subjective, a concentration-camp sadist’s values would be as good and as moral as the values<br />

of the world’s greatest creators.<br />

The years between my first meetings with Ayn Rand and the publication of Atlas Shrugged<br />

spanned my sophomore through senior years in college. In that time, I experienced serious<br />

intellectual doubt in connection with my ability to defend capitalism. What I had learned<br />

from <strong>Mises</strong> enabled me decisively to answer practically every argument that had been raised<br />

against capitalism prior to 1930, which was more than enough to answer my high school<br />

teachers. But my college professors presented a different challenge. They were teaching<br />

Keynesianism and the doctrine of pure and perfect competition/imperfect competition. <strong>Mises</strong>,<br />

I reluctantly had to conclude, had not dealt adequately with these doctrines. (This conclusion<br />

may appear somewhat ironic in view of the fact that what is today accepted as a new and<br />

convincing major critique of Keynesianism, namely, the “rational expectations doctrine,” is<br />

nothing more than arguments made by <strong>Mises</strong> and Hazlitt in the 1950s, for which they have<br />

received no credit.) At any rate, these were two major areas in which I found myself unable<br />

to turn to his writings for the kind of decisive help I had come to expect from him.<br />

The doubts I experienced in college were not in response to any kind of solid arguments,<br />

but more in response to phantoms of arguments that could not be grasped in any<br />

clear, precise way and that in fact usually bore obvious absurdities. This last was certainly<br />

true of the Keynesian multiplier doctrine and of the claim on the part of the pure-andperfect<br />

competition doctrine that competition implied the absence of rivalry. Despite the<br />

absurdities all of the faculty and practically all of my fellow students at Columbia seemed<br />

perfectly at home with the doctrines and absolutely confident of their truth.<br />

If anyone concrete example can convey the intellectual dishonesty of Columbia’s<br />

economics department in those days, it was this. Namely, while neglecting to provide a

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!