29.11.2012 Views

The Ethics of Banking: Conclusions from the Financial Crisis (Issues ...

The Ethics of Banking: Conclusions from the Financial Crisis (Issues ...

The Ethics of Banking: Conclusions from the Financial Crisis (Issues ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Hyper-Incentivization and <strong>the</strong> Hubris <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Financial</strong> Manager 149<br />

on bonuses. According to Franke, <strong>the</strong> proportion <strong>of</strong> performance-related pay in <strong>the</strong><br />

remuneration <strong>of</strong> financial industry employees in Japan is below 70% whereas in <strong>the</strong><br />

USA and Europe it is over 85%. 2<br />

When salaries are extremely high, <strong>the</strong>re is a strong suspicion that <strong>the</strong> appetite<br />

for risk is also extremely high. Excessive salaries fuelled <strong>the</strong> risk-taking mentality.<br />

When even <strong>the</strong> shareholders are fixated on rapid financial returns above all else and<br />

have a high appetite for risk, <strong>the</strong>y appoint people to <strong>the</strong> head <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm who seek<br />

out <strong>the</strong>se risks. Both shareholders and managers want to see <strong>the</strong> share price rise and<br />

both think, “If it goes belly up, we’ll make a fast exit” – <strong>the</strong> investor can ditch <strong>the</strong><br />

share, <strong>the</strong> manager can ditch <strong>the</strong> firm. Shareholders with an eye on a quick buck<br />

appoint managers with an eye on a quick buck.<br />

<strong>The</strong> consequence is that <strong>the</strong> risks taken are unduly high. For financial brokers or<br />

managers, <strong>the</strong>se are made bearable by <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>y can pocket <strong>the</strong>ir bonuses<br />

and leave <strong>the</strong> firm <strong>the</strong>y have ruined, on <strong>the</strong> “Take <strong>the</strong> money and run!” principle,<br />

without being ruined <strong>the</strong>mselves. It is <strong>the</strong>refore necessary to limit executive salaries<br />

and reassess <strong>the</strong> bonus system in <strong>the</strong> light <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> link between managers’ inflated<br />

pay and <strong>the</strong>ir extreme appetite for risk. Never<strong>the</strong>less, essentially it remains a valid<br />

principle that <strong>the</strong> firm has <strong>the</strong> right and <strong>the</strong> duty to decide on its own executive<br />

remuneration scheme. It normally works well, because a firm does not have money<br />

to give away. 3 But in <strong>the</strong> light <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> financial crisis, we must conclude that this<br />

way <strong>of</strong> thinking – that <strong>the</strong> finance industry will not pay excessive sums to traders<br />

and financial brokers, if for no o<strong>the</strong>r reason than that salaries and bonuses represent<br />

costs – is too simple.<br />

<strong>The</strong> costs argument is too simple because <strong>the</strong> bonuses, despite <strong>the</strong>ir staggering<br />

size, are <strong>of</strong>ten negligible in comparison to <strong>the</strong> revenues generated and <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its that<br />

can be earned on such volumes. One example concerns probably <strong>the</strong> most massive<br />

loss ever caused by a trader, <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> Jérome Kerviel <strong>of</strong> Société Générale bank.<br />

Before <strong>the</strong> disaster, in 2007 Kerviel had made pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> 43 million euros for his<br />

bank. That year, he put in a request for <strong>the</strong> bank to pay him a bonus <strong>of</strong> 600,000<br />

euros. But <strong>the</strong> bank only awarded a bonus <strong>of</strong> half <strong>the</strong> amount he requested, 300,000<br />

euros. That is a requested bonus <strong>of</strong> 1.395% and an awarded bonus <strong>of</strong> 0.697% <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it generated by <strong>the</strong> employee – hardly a rate <strong>of</strong> commission to get worked<br />

up about in any o<strong>the</strong>r circumstances. 4 On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, all Kerviel did was what<br />

his employment contract demanded <strong>of</strong> him. He just happened to do it successfully,<br />

which is what is generally expected under an employment contract and, what is<br />

more, without <strong>the</strong> incentive <strong>of</strong> a bonus in o<strong>the</strong>r industries. So why should he earn<br />

a bonus at all? <strong>The</strong> next year, Kerviel made a loss <strong>of</strong> 4.9 billion euros on behalf <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> bank. He told <strong>the</strong> press that he had not done it out <strong>of</strong> any personal greed but for<br />

2 Ibid.<br />

3 If <strong>the</strong> only people appointed to a supervisory board are those who are known not to make any<br />

trouble over manager pay rises, <strong>the</strong> firm can still pay excessive salaries contrary to its own selfinterest<br />

as an institution.<br />

4 JAMES B. STEWART: “<strong>The</strong> Omen. How an Obscure Breton Trader Gamed Oversight Weaknesses<br />

in <strong>the</strong> <strong>Banking</strong> System”, <strong>The</strong> New Yorker (October 20, 2008), pp. 54–65, here p. 60.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!