03.06.2013 Views

FRANCE The

FRANCE The

FRANCE The

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Trends<br />

3. <strong>The</strong> policy framework<br />

<strong>The</strong> Italian old age pension system is compulsory and public. Before<br />

1996 it was based on the pay-as-you-go criterion, but the “Dini<br />

reform” of 1995 provides pensions based on the contribution<br />

principle, entirely for those employed after 1 January 1996, or in<br />

part, according to the number of years of contribution to the system<br />

ruling before 1996.<br />

In the old system, the retirement age was set at 60 years for females<br />

and 65 for males, but retirement was allowed also to those above 54<br />

years of age and 35 years of contributions, and to those with 37<br />

years of working life, independent of age. In the new regime the<br />

retirement age is flexible between 57 and 65 years of age, both for<br />

males and females, but retirement is also allowed after 40 years of<br />

contributions, independent of age.<br />

In the old system, the pension benefit (which reaches its limit after<br />

40 years of contribution) is calculated by multiplying the average<br />

wage/salary over a period depending on the years of contribution<br />

(last 10 years for those who had paid contributions for more than 18<br />

years on 31 December 1995 and the entire working life for the<br />

others) by the years of work and by a coefficient determined as<br />

follows. (1) In the private sector, for the working life before 31<br />

December 1992: 2% for the yearly incomes below 33,714 euro; 1.5%<br />

for the income bracket 33,714 – 44,840 euro; 1.25% for that of<br />

44,840 – 55,966 euro; 1% above the latter limit. (2) In the private<br />

sector, for the working life after 31 December 1992, the coefficients<br />

are: 1.6% for the second income bracket; 1.35% for the third; 1.1%<br />

for the income bracket 55,966 – 64,057 euro; 0.9% above the latter<br />

limit. (3) In the public sector it is equal to 2%. <strong>The</strong> pension benefit is<br />

indexed to consumer prices but not to wages/salaries.<br />

In the new system, which applies to those employed for the first time<br />

after 1 January 1996, the pension benefit is calculated by multiplying<br />

a coefficient (e) by an amount obtained by capitalising 33% of the<br />

wages/salaries obtained during the working life, annually adjusted<br />

for the average rate of growth of nominal GDP in the previous five<br />

years. <strong>The</strong> coefficient e reflects the life expectancy at the time of<br />

retirement and it increases with the actual retirement age. For<br />

example, for a worker retiring at the age of 57 the coefficient is today<br />

equal to 4.72%, but it increases to 6.12% for those retiring at 65. <strong>The</strong><br />

substitution rate (pension over the last wage/salary) in the new<br />

regime is thus inversely related to the difference between the rate of<br />

growth of the worker’s wage/salary and the rate of growth of GDP<br />

(whose long-term value is set at 1.5%). For example, for a rate of<br />

growth of GDP equal to 2%, the substitution rate of a worker who<br />

will pay contributions for 40 years and will retire at 65 is equal to<br />

67.4% if the rate of growth of his wage/salary is one percentage<br />

point above that of GDP; the rate falls to 57% if the former rate of<br />

growth is more than two percentage points above that of GDP. <strong>The</strong><br />

pension benefit is indexed to consumer prices but not to<br />

wages/salaries.<br />

For all the workers who contributed for less than 18 years to the<br />

previous regime, the contribution system is applied pro-rata (mixed<br />

system), whereas for those who had more than 18 years of<br />

contributions at the time of the reform the pension benefit is entirely<br />

calculated on the basis of the old rules.<br />

Recent attempts to build a second “pillar” of the pension system,<br />

based on capitalisation of contributions and (open and closed)<br />

pension funds has not yet been able to seriously take off. This<br />

integrative scheme should not be funded through the contributions<br />

sustaining the first pillar, but should draw on the TFR (funds<br />

belonging to the worker but retained and accumulated by the<br />

employer).<br />

In the private sector, the contribution rate of workers is equal to<br />

8.89% (plus 1% for the part of earnings exceeding 33,714 euro) and<br />

that of employers is 23.81%, 5 for a total of 32.7% (and for maximum<br />

yearly earnings equal to 73,332 euro for those employed after 1996,<br />

who belong to the capitalisation regime). <strong>The</strong> State provides<br />

transfers for assistance measures and for support to pension<br />

schemes. In the public sector, the contribution rate of workers is<br />

8.55% and that of the employer is 23.8% in the case of local<br />

authorities and 24.2% in the case of the state. <strong>The</strong> State provides<br />

transfers sufficient to cover the total pension expenditure.<br />

According to the “Nucleo di valutazione della spesa pensionistica”<br />

(the department of the Treasury in charge of monitoring social<br />

expenditure), in 2001 pension expenditure, which amounted to<br />

13.5% of GDP (the same value as in 2000 and 0.4 percentage points<br />

below that of 1999), was mostly financed by contributions. After<br />

remaining above 10% of GDP since 1996, in 2001 contributions<br />

amounted to 10.5% (as compared to the value of 10.3% recorded in<br />

2000, 10.5 in 1999, 10.2 in 1998 and in 1997). <strong>The</strong> GIAS (the<br />

department of the national institute for social protection, INPS, in<br />

charge of the management of assistance measure) financed<br />

expenditure for an amount equal to 2.2% of GDP (which has been<br />

fairly stable since 1998, when the borders between pensions and<br />

assistance measures were redefined by law). <strong>The</strong> deficit, which is<br />

mostly due to the state financing of the pension fund of state<br />

employees, was thus equal to 0.8% of GDP, as compared to the<br />

value of 1% recorded in 2000, 1.1 in 1999, 1.3 in 1998, 1.8 in 1997.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Stockholm European Council set the target of increasing the<br />

Union employment rate among the 55-64 up to 50% and the<br />

Barcelona Council proposed, according to the timing up to 2010 set<br />

for the employment rates, to increase the retirement age by five<br />

years. In line with these goals, the NAP 2002 sets, for the first time, a<br />

“plausible although ambitious” quantitative target: increase the<br />

employment rate among the 55-64 to 40% by 2005, from 28% in<br />

2001. 6<br />

This target requires, of course, the activation of wide-ranging<br />

policies, although the gradual phasing in of the pension reforms and<br />

further measure in the Government agenda (in particular, the<br />

increases in minimum retirement age), to be discussed below, should<br />

strengthen the recent positive trends in old age employment rates<br />

(see Table 9), improving also those for males.<br />

Some steps towards the achievement of such targets are contained<br />

in the Budget Law (Legge Finanziaria) 2002, which passed in<br />

Parliament on 23 December 2002. <strong>The</strong> prohibition to cumulate<br />

pensions and income from work was abolished for those who retire<br />

at minimum 58 years of age and with 37 years of contribution. <strong>The</strong><br />

same applies to those already retired on 1 December 2002, even<br />

though these individuals will have to pay a certain amount<br />

depending on their age and contribution history at the time of<br />

retirement. A ratification (“sanatoria”) is available for the<br />

pensioners who illegally worked in the black market.<br />

<strong>The</strong> general lines of action which the Government wishes to pursue<br />

5 Employers pay contributions also for illness and motherhood (3.09% for blue-collar and 0.87% for white-collar workers); unemployment (4.71% for both types of<br />

workers) and family support (2.48% for both types of workers).<br />

6 It is worth reminding that the targets set for the total employment rate and the female one are set, respectively, at 58.5% (an increase of 3.6 percentage points) and<br />

46.0% (an increase of 4.7 percentage points).<br />

120 Spring 2003 | European Employment Observatory Review

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!