21.12.2013 Views

Hayek's The Constitution of Liberty - Institute of Economic Affairs

Hayek's The Constitution of Liberty - Institute of Economic Affairs

Hayek's The Constitution of Liberty - Institute of Economic Affairs

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

h ay e k ’ s t h e c o n s t i t u t i o n o f l i b e r t y<br />

s a f e g ua r d i n g p r o g r e s s<br />

much larger agricultural workforce than markets alone would<br />

require. <strong>The</strong> primary tools <strong>of</strong> this misguided policy are subsidies<br />

and controls. Price supports and other farm subsidies amount to<br />

‘compulsory transfers <strong>of</strong> income from the urban to the agricultural<br />

population.’ More dangerous, in terms <strong>of</strong> direct coercion,<br />

are efforts to control prices and production. Current agricultural<br />

policy, to be successful, requires authoritative decisions as to ‘who<br />

is to produce, how much, and what.’ Such a policy leaves little<br />

room for individual freedom and leads towards ‘a totalitarian<br />

control <strong>of</strong> all economic activity’ (362; cf. 360, 361–2).<br />

How might government properly address the genuine and<br />

important problems faced by agricultural workers? In Hayek’s<br />

view, no planning is needed in this area. Generally economic<br />

markets should be allowed to take their course. Only the pressure<br />

<strong>of</strong> prices, by producing ‘the necessary reduction in the agricultural<br />

population’ and encouraging the adoption <strong>of</strong> new agricultural<br />

techniques, can ‘lower cost and make the survival <strong>of</strong> the<br />

suitable units possible.’ Beyond this, there are two specific functions<br />

that government ought to perform. First, it should gradually<br />

improve legal institutions with a view to making markets work<br />

more effectively. Here Hayek takes note <strong>of</strong> the benefits derived<br />

in medieval Europe from the consolidation <strong>of</strong> dispersed holdings<br />

and in England from enclosures <strong>of</strong> the commons. His point is that<br />

legal changes might still be required to bring ‘appropriate units<br />

<strong>of</strong> enterprise under single control’ and to foster ‘group collaboration.’<br />

Achieving this result might require ‘compulsory expropriation,’<br />

but with proper safeguards. Second, government ought to<br />

provide a variety <strong>of</strong> services to agricultural workers, especially<br />

informing them about the benefits <strong>of</strong> technological innovations<br />

(see 360, 364–5).<br />

Natural resource policy<br />

<strong>The</strong> latter half <strong>of</strong> Chapter 23 addresses indirectly this enduring<br />

question: how is humankind to regard ‘a free gift <strong>of</strong> nature’?<br />

With some exceptions, Hayek views nature’s gifts as an available<br />

supply or ‘resource’ to be used in fostering economic progress.<br />

Much government policy, by contrast, is premised on the idea<br />

that natural resources have a special standing, such that they must<br />

be preserved and protected from exploitation by private enterprise,<br />

even with far-reaching controls that greatly limit individual<br />

freedom. Hayek replies that a natural resource should be treated<br />

the same way as other resources, such as ‘man-made equipment<br />

or human capacities,’ that might be invested in productive activity<br />

(367, 373–4).<br />

Hayek points out that some natural resources are diminished<br />

by use and are eventually used up, while others can be so managed<br />

as to yield a durable stream <strong>of</strong> benefits. In either case, however, he<br />

has no objection to exhausting a natural resource, if that appears<br />

to be the best strategy to maximise income. <strong>The</strong> market <strong>of</strong>fers<br />

better foresight in these matters than government planning; and<br />

one lesson <strong>of</strong> advancing technology has been that new and unanticipated<br />

resources will emerge to replace existing ones (368–70,<br />

374).<br />

Most <strong>of</strong> the arguments for ‘government control <strong>of</strong> private<br />

activity in the interest <strong>of</strong> conservation <strong>of</strong> natural resources’ are, in<br />

Hayek’s view, invalid. He recognises an exception, however, where<br />

the aim is not income maximisation, but providing recreational<br />

opportunities and preserving natural beauty or sites <strong>of</strong> historical<br />

or scientific interest. Such amenities render a service to the public<br />

at large, providing advantages for which the individual beneficiary<br />

cannot be charged a price. Also, they usually require large tracts<br />

174<br />

175

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!