21.12.2013 Views

Hayek's The Constitution of Liberty - Institute of Economic Affairs

Hayek's The Constitution of Liberty - Institute of Economic Affairs

Hayek's The Constitution of Liberty - Institute of Economic Affairs

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

h ay e k ’ s t h e c o n s t i t u t i o n o f l i b e r t y<br />

t h e u s e a n d l i m i t s o f k n o w l e d g e<br />

time rules were no more than behavioural dispositions. <strong>The</strong>ir<br />

articulation in speech and in writing came very late in the process<br />

<strong>of</strong> human evolution; and even now, our compliance with rules has<br />

mostly a subconscious and habitual character.<br />

Hayek frames the story <strong>of</strong> human evolution in terms <strong>of</strong> the<br />

genesis, diffusion and transmission <strong>of</strong> rules. Elements <strong>of</strong> this<br />

story appear in <strong>The</strong> <strong>Constitution</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Liberty</strong>, but it is presented much<br />

more clearly in later writings. In his most detailed account <strong>of</strong> the<br />

matter, Hayek identifies three stages <strong>of</strong> evolution, each <strong>of</strong> which<br />

involves rule-governed behaviour, but with great variation in both<br />

the character <strong>of</strong> the rules and the behaviour itself. This account is<br />

necessarily conjectural, since it looks back at least a million years,<br />

long before the beginnings <strong>of</strong> recorded history.<br />

Hayek speculates that primitive society consisted <strong>of</strong> small<br />

bands <strong>of</strong> 15 to 40 persons, who lived by hunting and gathering.<br />

Its rules were nothing more than instinctive dispositions to act<br />

in ways that favoured group solidarity and survival. How did<br />

general rules emerge? Hayek attaches great importance to the<br />

mind’s facility <strong>of</strong> treating particulars as members <strong>of</strong> a class – what<br />

he calls ‘abstraction.’ Verbal statements are a clear example, but<br />

so are our behavioural responses. Abstraction ‘manifests itself<br />

also in the way in which we respond similarly to any one <strong>of</strong> a<br />

class <strong>of</strong> events which in most respects may be very different from<br />

one another, and the feelings which are evoked by those events<br />

and which guide our action, be it a sense <strong>of</strong> justice or <strong>of</strong> moral or<br />

aesthetic approval or disapproval’ (40, 452, n. 4; cf. Hayek, 1952a:<br />

142–6; and Hayek, 1978a: 35–49). This subconscious, responsive<br />

form <strong>of</strong> abstraction developed as human beings moved through<br />

different social structures; and the most efficient <strong>of</strong> these abstract<br />

behavioural rules were spread through imitation (observers<br />

acquired the rule by imitating particular actions that exemplified<br />

it) and were enforced by social pressures. <strong>The</strong> verbal articulation<br />

<strong>of</strong> learnt rules began about eight thousand years ago, and written<br />

codes <strong>of</strong> morality and law are much more recent. Even after these<br />

developments, subconscious abstraction would continue to exert<br />

a dominant influence on human action (see 61–7, 148–9, 151–2;<br />

Hayek, 1973: 17–21, 74–6; Hayek, 1979: 159–61).<br />

Our present stock <strong>of</strong> knowledge consists in large degree <strong>of</strong><br />

rules that we have acquired through habit, custom and tradition.<br />

Social evolution tends to be cumulative, so that traces <strong>of</strong> earlier<br />

rules are brought forward into the present, where they exist in a<br />

layered or stratified form.<br />

Using contemporaneous knowledge: imitation, prices<br />

and esteem<br />

Transmission in time is one <strong>of</strong> the ways by which knowledge<br />

becomes available for our use. <strong>The</strong> other way is through communication<br />

among contemporaries, three examples <strong>of</strong> which are: a)<br />

‘individuals imitating those who have been more successful;’ b)<br />

individuals being guided by ‘prices <strong>of</strong>fered for their products;’ and<br />

c) individuals responding to ‘expressions <strong>of</strong> moral or aesthetic<br />

esteem for their having observed standards <strong>of</strong> conduct’ (28–9).<br />

All three processes are vital to civilisation. Imitation is essential<br />

to society’s adaptive evolution, where ‘the decisive factor is not the<br />

selection <strong>of</strong> the physical and inheritable properties <strong>of</strong> the individuals<br />

but the selection by imitation <strong>of</strong> successful institutions and<br />

habits’ (59). Prices convey vital information about the economic<br />

behaviour <strong>of</strong> dispersed individuals. Signs <strong>of</strong> approval or disapproval<br />

promote conformity to rules.<br />

56<br />

57

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!