11.03.2014 Views

Dissertation_Paula Aleksandrowicz_12 ... - Jacobs University

Dissertation_Paula Aleksandrowicz_12 ... - Jacobs University

Dissertation_Paula Aleksandrowicz_12 ... - Jacobs University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

about by profit considerations in the first place and social norms matter insofar as they<br />

influence the purchasing behaviour of customers. Most likely, those two factors are<br />

intertwined: If companies comply with social expectations and norms, they are recognised<br />

as a ´good practice´ company and visited by a higher number of customers. If, on the<br />

contrary, companies do not respect those expectations, they run the risk of being listed in the<br />

„Black Book of Brand Corporations”. Moreover, firms have sometimes to choose between<br />

different efficiency considerations. E.g., firms may pursue their economic interest even if<br />

they run the risk of sanctions by state actors. An example is the frequent bypassing of the<br />

former § 147a SGB III in Germany, which ultimately had led to more leniency of the state<br />

actors towards companies shedding their workforce (Teipen 2003: 88-9).<br />

Because of those restrictions of the institutionalist approach, I lean towards a<br />

combination of rational choice and institutional theories, as has been employed by<br />

Mayntz/Scharpf (1995), Scharpf (1997) or Windhoff-Héritier (1991). That framework is<br />

labelled ‘actor-centred institutionalism’ (Scharpf 1997, Mayntz/Scharpf 1995), ’rational<br />

choice institutionalism’ (Thelen 1999) or given some other names depending on the<br />

researcher (Scharpf 1997: 36). While institutionalism locates the central decision organ at<br />

the societal macro level, actor-centred institutionalism stresses that partial power still<br />

remains with the organisations. Scharpf (1997: 36) justifies the combination of actor-centred<br />

and institution-centred models with the realisation that policy processes cannot be analysed<br />

by institutional or rational-choice theories alone as that would reduce the analysis to one<br />

dimension.<br />

Scharpf (1997: 38) understands institutions in the narrow sense of “systems or rules that<br />

structure the courses of actions that a set of actors may choose”, e.g. formal legal rules – in<br />

my case, collective bargaining law, labour law, pension law, company law – as well as<br />

“informal rules, norms, conventions, and expectations” of a normatively binding character.<br />

The role of institutions is to delineate “the feasible set” of choices. Mayntz/Scharpf (1995:<br />

43) delimit their concept from classic institutionalism with the fact that their framework<br />

does not view institutional influence as deterministic and recognises influences of collective<br />

actors upon institutions. Moreover, actor-centred institutionalism includes also nongovernmental<br />

institutions in the observation.<br />

The actor-centred institutionalism developed by Mayntz and Scharpf (1995) fits my idea<br />

of the interactions between actors in the field of pension and labour market policy.<br />

Following this approach, I view institutional factors (first and foremost the system of old-<br />

<strong>12</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!