26.12.2014 Views

1qGLG9p

1qGLG9p

1qGLG9p

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Discussions 89<br />

He also agreed with the permanent shock framework and thought that the<br />

measurement of time-varying potential output growth matched well his views<br />

of the crisis, including the time-varying capacity to repay debt. However, he<br />

did not share the report’s alarmist view of emerging economies. The situation is<br />

worse in the developed economies than in the emerging economies. Some data<br />

inconsistencies plague the comparison of leverage between the US, Europe and<br />

the emerging economies. Leverage is overestimated for Europe and the emerging<br />

markets relative to the US. Causality is also uncertain – is leverage the reason for<br />

low growth, or vice versa<br />

Ginguené added a few points:<br />

• The increase in leverage in emerging economies is largely a Chinese<br />

phenomenon.<br />

• Given that nominal interest rates and nominal GDP growth are strongly<br />

co-integrated, it is appropriate to use a time-varying discount factor as<br />

is done in the report.<br />

• If the trend is set without considering the crisis, then the results are<br />

very different from if the trend is calculated including the crisis. When<br />

including the crisis, the permanent shock can be interpreted as the<br />

adjustment of excess growth and leverage before the crisis.<br />

• This is why the direction of causality between leverage and growth<br />

becomes quite opaque.<br />

• The debt Laffer curve introduced in the report is quite original and<br />

useful.<br />

Atif Mian, Princeton University<br />

Atif Mian agreed that we have not yet seen a significant deleveraging at the global<br />

level or a decline in debt. Instead, we have seen a continuous increase in leverage<br />

along with a decline in growth, which from a sustainability perspective leaves<br />

some questions that need to be addressed.<br />

The fundamental problem we face is two-fold: leverage before and after<br />

the crisis. Before the crisis, leverage increased at a time of sustained economic<br />

growth, falling real interest rates and no inflationary pressure. After the crisis, as<br />

the authors point out, leverage kept rising as private debt turned into public debt<br />

and debt levels increased in emerging market economies, such as China. Debt<br />

could be the fundamental problem; alternatively, debt could be the symptom of<br />

deeper problems in the economy.<br />

As noted by Thomas Piketty, the median income in the US has remained<br />

stagnant since the 1970s. If income accumulates at the top of the income<br />

distribution, increases in savings by already high-saving top earners mean that<br />

the economy will have a hard time equilibrating supply and demand, unless there<br />

is way to fill the gap by the issuance of more debt. This is what has happened in<br />

the US. Leverage is a symptom of the economy trying to balance itself.<br />

The Chinese economy, instead, relied on someone borrowing and buying its<br />

goods. Before the crisis, outsiders leveraged and borrowed to buy Chinese goods,<br />

but when outsiders stop leveraging then the domestic economy needs to generate

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!